The Stock Market as a Leading Indicator An Application of Granger Causality

Post on: 7 Май, 2015 No Comment

The Stock Market as a Leading Indicator An Application of Granger Causality

The Stock Market As A Leading Indicator: An Application Of Granger Causality

Brad Comincioli

Illinois Wesleyan

The University Avenue Undergraduate Journal of Economics, Sample Issue (1996)

I. INTRODUCTION

The stock market has traditionally been viewed as an indicator or predictor of the economy. Many believe that large decreases in stock prices are reflective of a future recession, whereas large increases in stock prices suggest future economic growth.

The stock market as an indicator of economic activity, however, does not go without controversy. Skeptics point to the strong economic growth that followed the 1987 stock market crash as reason to doubt the stock market’s predictive ability. Given the controversy that surrounds the stock market as an indicator of future economic activity, it seems relevant to further research this topic.

Theoretical reasons for why stock prices might predict economic activity include the traditional valuation model of stock prices and the wealth effect. The traditional valuation model of stock prices suggests that stock prices reflect expectations about the future economy, and can therefore predict the economy. The wealth effect contends that stock prices lead economic activity by actually causing what happens to the economy.

The purpose of this paper, then, is to evaluate stock prices as a leading indicator of economic activity. Time-series analysis and the notion of Granger causality are used in this project to estimate relationships between stock prices and the economy, and to see if they are consistent with theory.

In this paper, we will explore the following questions. First, does the stock market lead the real economy, in the sense that variation in its past values explains some of the variation in the real economy? Second, does the stock market Granger-cause the real economy, in which case past values of stock prices improve the prediction of future economic activity? And third, does the real economy Granger-cause the stock market, in that past values of economic activity improve the prediction of the stock market?

II. CAN THE STOCK MARKET PREDICT ECONOMIC ACTIVITY?

The question of whether the stock market can predict the economy has been widely debated. Those who support the market’s predictive ability argue that the stock market is forward-looking, and current prices reflect the future earnings potential, or profitability, of corporations. Since stock prices reflect expectations about profitability, and profitability is directly linked to economic activity, fluctuations in stock prices are thought to lead the direction of the economy. If the economy is expected to enter into a recession, for example, the stock market will anticipate this by bidding down the prices of stocks.

The wealth effect is also regarded as support for the stock market’s predictive ability. Pearce (1983) argues that since fluctuations in stock prices have a direct effect on aggregate spending, the economy can be predicted from the stock market. When the stock market is rising, investors are more wealthy and spend more. As a result, the economy expands. On the other hand, if stock prices are declining, investors are less wealthy and spend less. This results in slower economic growth.

Critics, however, point to a number of reasons not to trust the stock market as an indicator of future economic activity. Pearce (1983) argues that the stock market has previously generated false signals about the economy, and therefore, should not be relied on as an economic indicator. The 1987 stock market crash is one example in which stock prices falsely predicted the direction of the economy. Instead of entering into a recession which many were expecting, the economy continued to grow until the early 1990’s (see FIGURE 1).

FIGURE 1: Does the Stock Market Predict the Economy?

Another reason why skeptics do not trust the stock market as an indicator of the economy is because of investors’ expectations. Critics reason that expectations about future economic activity are subject to human error, which in many cases causes stock prices to deviate from the real economy. Since investors do not always anticipate correctly, stock prices will sometimes increase before the economy enters into recession and decrease before the economy expands. As a result, the stock market will often mislead the direction of the economy.

Even when stock prices do precede economic activity, a question that arises is how much lead or lag time should the market be allowed. For example, do decreases in stock prices today signal a recession in six months, one year, two years, or will a recession even occur? An examination of historical data yields mixed results with respect to the stock market’s predictive ability. Douglas Pearce (1983) found support for stock prices leading the direction of the economy. His study discovered that from 1956-1983, stock prices generally started to decline two to four quarters before recessions began. Pearce also found that stock prices began to rise in all cases before the beginning of an economic expansion, usually about midway through the contraction.

Other studies have found evidence that does not support the stock market as a leading economic indicator. A study by Peek and Rosenberg (1988), for example, indicates that between 1955 and 1986, out of eleven cases in which the Standard and Poor’s Composite Index of 500 stocks (S&P500) declined by more than 7 percent (the smallest pre-recession decline in the S&P500), only six were followed by recessions. Furthermore, a study conducted by Robert J. Barro (1989) found that stock prices predicted three recessions for the years 1963, 1967, and 1978, that did not occur.

III. WHY STOCK PRICES MIGHT LEAD THE ECONOMY

One theoretical reason why stock prices might lead economic activity is based on the traditional equity valuation model shown below (Brealey and Myers 1988) :

where profitability is the expected amount of corporate earnings, and k is the rate at which profitability is discounted. It is usually assumed that k is constant.

According to this equation, stock prices equal the present value of a company’s expected future profits. If profitability is expected to increase (holding k constant), the price of the stock will increase. Conversely, if investors are expecting a firm’s profits to decline in the future, then the price of the stock will decrease in value.

Since a firm’s profits are directly linked to the behavior of the real economy, stock prices will be affected by expectations about the future economy. For example, if investors expect the economy to enter into recession, then expected profits will be diminished and stock prices will decrease in value. On the other hand, if investors anticipate economic growth, then expected profits will improve and stock prices will increase. Thus, investors have an interest in predicting the future real economy. And, if they are somewhat successful in their predictions, then stock price movements will lead the direction of the economy.

An issue to point out here is how investors form their expectations. There are a number of models that attempt to explain how expectations are formed (see, for example, DeBondt and Thaler 1985. and Pearce and Roley 1985 ). Such models include the adaptive expectations model and the rational expectations model. Adaptive expectations models suggest that expectations are developed through past experience, whereas rational expectations models pose that expectations are formed using all current information that is available. Although these models are not the focus of this paper, it is important to understand that stock prices are highly dependent on investors’ expectations. To some extent, these models assume that expectations arise out of experience or historical data. A change in recent experience, then, can cause investors to change their expectations about the future real economy, which then causes them to bid up or down the prices of stocks. To the extent that these models are true, the economy may also lead the stock market.

The wealth effect from fluctuations in stock prices is another theoretical argument for why stock prices might lead the economy. Traditional macroeconomic models often assume that consumption depends not just on income, but also on wealth. Increases and decreases in stock prices raise and lower wealth, which in turn raise and lower aggregate consumption. And, because consumption is a large part of the economy, changes in the real economy are observed.

In summary, according to fundamental valuation models, stock prices depend on expectations about the future economy. Therefore, expected changes in the real economy cause the values of stock prices. According to the wealth effect, however, changes in stock prices cause the variation in the real economy. It is important to point out that, while the causation in the two theories is different, both theories suggest that the stock market predicts the economy.

IV. DATA

The sample data cover the period 1970:IQ-1994:IIIQ and contain a total of 99 quarterly observations. The variable that is used to measure movements in stock prices is the quarterly percent change in the Standard and Poor’s Composite Index of 500 stocks (SP500). The reason for choosing the S&P500 rather than other stock indexes is because it is a fairly representative measure of the stock market. Other indexes such as the Dow Jones Industrial Average, which measures the performance of only 30 blue-chip companies, are less representative. The fact the S&P500 Index is a value-weighted as opposed to a price-weighted index is another reason this index was chosen. One final reason for choosing the S&P500 Index is because it is included as one of the twelve components in the Department of Commerce’s index of leading economic indicators.

The Stock Market as a Leading Indicator An Application of Granger Causality

The variable used to measure changes in real economic activity is the quarterly percent change of real Gross Domestic Product (GDP). In using real values of GDP, the year 1987 is used as the base year for the implicit price deflator. Other studies utilized percent changes in the Index of Industrial Production as their proxy for economic growth, but did not indicate that it was a better measure of economic activity.

V. TESTING FOR GRANGER CAUSALITY

The procedure for testing statistical causality between stock prices and the economy is the direct Granger-causality test proposed by C. J. Granger in 1969. Granger causality may have more to do with precedence, or prediction, than with causation in the usual sense. It suggests that while the past can cause/predict the future, the future cannot cause/predict the past.

According to Granger, X causes Y if the past values of X can be used to predict Y more accurately than simply using the past values of Y. In other words, if past values of X statistically improve the prediction of Y, then we can conclude that X Granger-causes Y.

It should be pointed out that given the controversy surrounding the Granger causality method, our empirical results and conclusions drawn from them should be considered as suggestive rather than absolute. This is especially important in light of the false signals that the stock market has generated in the past.

Our first step in testing for Granger causality is to determine whether there is a trend in our sample data. An important assumption in any time-series analysis is that the variables being tested are stationary. Figure 1 demonstrates how this assumption is violated. During the period 1970-1994, both Real GDP and the S&P500 Index follow an upward trend. In order to eliminate the trend, we form percent changes in the two variables and then examine if the two are stationary (see FIGURE 2). Since the two variables do not appear to have a trend, we reason that the percent changes are stationary and proceed with the Granger test.

Our next step in testing for Granger causality is to test whether a relationship exists between stock prices and the economy. In order for causality to hold true, a relationship must already exist between the variables being tested. For example, if X was not related to Y, then how could X possibly cause the variation in Y?

FIGURE 2: Testing for Stationarity

Figure 3

To determine whether a relationship exists between stock prices and the economy, we regress %GDP on past values of %SP500, lagged back 6 quarters:

%GDP= a + b(%SP500-1 ) + c(%SP500-2 ) + d(%SP500-3 ) + e(SP500-4 ) + f(%SP500-5 ) + g(%SP500-6 ) + u

The results of this regression indicate that stock prices are positively related to the economy when lagged as much as three quarters (see Table 1). Moreover, stock prices lagged one quarter are both positive and statistically significant at the .01 level. As a result, we conclude that there is a relationship between past values of stock prices and the economy. Thus, the results from this regression suggest that past values of stock prices do lead economic behavior, but this does not imply that stock prices Granger-cause the economy. Formal tests of causality are exhibited later in the paper.


Categories
Stocks  
Tags
Here your chance to leave a comment!