Institutional Trading Information Production and Corporate SpinOffs
Post on: 24 Июнь, 2015 No Comment
Thomas J. Chemmanur*
Boston College
Shan He**
Louisiana State University
August 2008
* Professor of Finance, Fulton Hall 330, Carroll School of Management, Boston College, Chestnut Hill, MA 02467.
Phone: 617-552-3980. Fax: 617-552-0431. E-mail: chemmanu@bc.edu.
** Assistant Professor of Finance, Patrick F. Taylor Hall 2158, E.J. Ourso School of Business, Louisiana State
University, Baton Rouge, LA 70803. Phone: 225-578-6335. Fax: 225-578-6366. E-mail: shanhe@lsu.edu.
We would like to thank the Millstein Center for Co rporate Governance and Performance, Yale Univ ersity, for
research support. For helpful comments and discussions, we thank Yawen Jiao, Debarshi Nandy, Gang Hu, Mark
Liu, Wayne F erson, a nd Jef f Po ntiff. We al so t hank s eminar part icipants at B oston C ollege, L ouisiana St ate
University, Un iversity o f New Hampshire, Florid a St ate Un iversity, an d con ference p articipants at th e First
Singapore International C onference on Fi nance at t he National U niversity of Si ngapore, t he Shareholders an d
Corporate Governance Conference at Oxford University, the 2008 China International Conference in Finance at
Dalian, the AsianFA-NFA 2008 international conference at Yokohama, and the FM A annual meetings for helpful
comments. We thank the Abel/Noser Corporation for providing us with their institutional trading data, and Judy
Maiorca for answering many data related questions. We remain responsible for all errors and omissions
Page 2
Institutional Trading, Information Production, and Corporate Spin-offs
Abstract
Using a large sam ple of proprietary transaction-level institutional trading dat a, we em pirically
analyze, for the first time in the literature, the role of institutional investors in corporate spin-offs. In the
first part of t he paper, we study the im balance in post-spin-off institutional tra ding between parent and
subsidiary, and analyze this imbalance to test three different hypotheses regarding institutional investors’
role in spin-offs: information prod uction, pure pla y, and risk management. In the second part of the
paper, we ex amine the information production role of institutional inv estors in detail by analyzing the
predictability of institutional trading around corporate spin-offs for the short-term and the long-term stock
returns following spin-of fs. In the thi rd part of th e paper, we study the pat tern and profitabilit y of
institutional trading following spin-offs. Our empirical results can be summarized as follows. First, there
is significant i mbalance i n post-spin-off institutiona l trading between parent s and subsidiaries; this
imbalance increases corresponding t o the differ
characterizing the two entities, beta risk, and long-t erm growth prospects. Second, institutional trading in
the combined firm two months prior to the spin-off has significant predictive power for the announcement
effect of a sp in-off. Third, institutional trading in the subsidiary immediately after spin-off co mpletion
also has predictive power for its subsequent long-term stock returns; this predictive power is greater when
the subsidiary’s size constitutes only a smaller fraction of the combined firm’s size. Fourth, the predictive
power of institutional trading is weaker for the parent firm’s long-term returns; further, unlike in the case
of the subsidiary. institutional invest ors start expl oiting t heir private infor mation after the spin-off
announcement, but before the spin-off is com pleted. Finally, institutional investors are able to realize
superior profits by trading in the equity of the subsidiary in the first quarter after the spin-off. While our
results provi de some support for all three hypothe ses re garding the role of institutional i nvestors in
corporate spin-offs, they provide particularly strong support for the information production hypothesis.
JEL classification: G32, G34, G14
Keywords: Corporate Spin-offs, Instit utional investors, Institutional trading, Inform ation production.
ence in the extent of inform ation asy mmetry
Page 3
Institutional Trading, Information Production, and Corporate Spin-offs
1. Introduction
In the last fe w years, there has been a considerable increase in c orporate spin-off activity. This
increase in spin-offs has been partly attributed to institutional investors’ preferences, and their pressure on
firm managers to undertake spin-offs.1 Both the academic and pract itioner literature has conjectured that
breaking up a conglomerate into “pure play” companies may benefit institutional investors such as mutual
funds in several way s, while sim ultaneously resulting in an increase in the share price of the firm
conducting the spin-off. For example, in a recent theoretical paper, Chemmanur and Liu (2005) show that,
in a setting with asymmetric information between firm insiders and outsiders re garding the firm ’s true
value, an undervalued firm can improve its stock price through a spin-off. The basic idea in their paper is
that a spin-off can increase inform ation production by institutional investors about the firm. so that, in
equilibrium, firm insiders with favorable private information (i.e. with severely undervalued equity) will
choose to conduct a spin- off, increasing their firm ’s share price. However, there has been no em pirical
research on the role of institutional in vestors in corporate spin-offs. The objective of this paper is to fill
this gap in the literature b y analyzing empirically the role of institutional investors in spin-offs, making
use of a large sample of transaction-level institutional trading data, for the first time in the literature.2
Institutional investors may play three different roles around corporate spin-offs, as suggested b y
the academic and practitioner-oriented literature on spin -offs. The first possible role is the “i nformation
production” role (Chemmanur and Li u (2005)), which suggests that a spin-off can increase information
1 For example, the important role played by institutional investors in corporate spin-offs is reflected in the following
quote from an article in the Financial Times (October 28, 2005) that attributes the recent breakups of conglomerates
to a shift in investor preference: “But a new backlash against conglomerates suggests a more lasting shift in investor
preferences may be taking place — driven in part by the growing influence of hedge funds and private equity houses.
In pub lic m arkets, big has rarely ap peared less b eautiful. In the US, the m ost visi ble sign is the break-up of
companies such as Cendant, the sprawling leisure group behind Avis rental cars and the Orbitz travel website, which
this week announced a four-way demerger to try to lift its flagging share price. It follows a similar decision by Barry
Dillers InterActive Corporation to spin off its Expedia travel site and the breaking apart of Viacom, a media empire
that owns CBS television network, MTV and Paramount Pictures.”
2 There is a growing literature on the role of institutional investors around other corporate events: see, e.g. Parrino,
Sias, and Starks (2003), who study the role of institutional investors around forced CEO turnovers.
Page 4
production a bout t he ind ividual di visions of the f irm by i nstitutional in vestors, and th us helps th e
company to “unlock hidden value”.3 The second possi ble role of institutional investors in a s pin-off can
be thought of as “risk management”. The risk management role suggests that institutional investors can
manage their own risk better after a spin-off b y better allocat ing their invest ment acro ss stocks o f
different risk classes after a spin-off rather than leaving asset allocation to conglomerate fir ms.4 In other
words, a portfolio m anager desiring a high-risk po rtfolio can invest in the higher risk division of a
conglomerate firm after a spin-off, while another p ortfolio manager desiring a low-risk p ortfolio can
invest in the lower risk division; clearly, such fine-tuning of risk is not possible in the absen ce of a spin-
off. If such risk manage ment benefits are ind eed present, a spin-off may increase the de mand for the
firm’s equity from institutional investors, increasing st ock price. The third possible role of institutional
investors in a spin-off can be referred as “pure play ”. The pure play role sugg ests that spi n-offs allow
institutions (e.g. mutual funds) to fine-t une their in vestments in a firm ’s equity according t o their own
fund investors’ preferences. For example, growth funds can invest in the high-growth divisions, and value
funds can invest in lower growth divisions (whi ch may gener ate more r eliable cash fl ows) of a
conglomerate firm after a spin-off. Since many U.S. mutual funds are marketed to investors as “growth
funds” or “value funds”, splitting conglomerates into pure play companies can make the shares of the
resulting firms more attractive to those funds, i ncreasing demand for these shares and consequentl y their
3 Many firms claim that the objective of their proposed spin-offs is to “unlock value”. For example, a recent article
in the Financial Times (October 25, 2005) commenting on Cendant’s spin-offs said: “Cendant’s planned split echoes
moves by other large conglomerates such as Viacom, the media group, to spin off units in order to ‘unlock value’ for
investors.”
4 Institutional investors’ preference to manage their own risk is also cited as a factor that led to the Cendant spin-off
as well as other recent spin-offs. To quote an article regarding the Cendant spin-off in the Financial Times (October
28, 2005): “Henry Silverman, chief executive of Cendant, argues that the rise of hedge funds has undermined one of
the greatest attractio ns of big diversified companies: their ability to manage risk and produce consistent earnings.
These most active of traders would rather allocate assets themselves than outsource the risk to com pany managers.
‘Investors dont want portfolios (from companies) any more,’ he says. Fund managers have long claimed they prefer
to allocate assets among sectors rather than leave it to conglomerates, but hedge funds take this to a new extreme by
actively seeking out volatility and risk in order to offset it ag ainst investments elsewhere. … Cendant — which had
been carefully constructed to balance risk across sectors and different stages of the economic cycle — says it came to
have more than half its sh ares held by hedge funds, leaving it li ttle choice but to give them the more focused
investment opportunities they crave.”
Page 5
price.5 The above three roles are clearly not mutually exclusive: institutional investors may perform all of
these roles ar ound corporate spin-offs. We will discu ss the three roles of institutional investors around
corporate spin-offs in more detail and develop testable hypotheses in section 2.
The objective of this paper is to develop an empirical analysis of the role of institutional investors
in corporate spin-offs, for t he first time in the literature. In particular, we make use of a large sam ple of
proprietary transaction-level institutional trading data to analy ze whether institutional invest ors perform
one or more of the three roles discussed above around corporate spin-offs. Further, we study the
information production role of institutional investors in more detail by study ing the information content,
pattern, and profitability of institutional trading around corporate sp in-offs. Our data include transactions
from January 1999 to December 2004 which were o riginated from 531 different institutions (with a total
annualized trading princi pal of $4. 61 trillion over all U.S. equities). There were altogether 66
conglomerates that had spin-offs dur ing this period. Our sam ple institutions engaged in about 16%, in
terms of dollar value, of t he CRSP reported trading volume in the shares of these spin-offs firms. With
this dataset, we are able to track institutional trading in the shares of these spin -off firms both before and
after spin-off co mpletion. For the post-spin-off subsidiaries, w e identify institutional trading int o two
categories, namely, institutional share allocation sales (i.e. selling of shares allocated to the i nstitutions’
account through the pr o-rata distribution in spin- offs) and institutional post-s pin-off secondary market
trading (i.e. buying and selling of shares in the spin-off firms by institutions in the secondary market after
the spin-offs). This allows us to analyze the trading pattern and pr ofitability for these two categories of
transactions separately.
The paper is organized into three parts. In the fi rst part of the paper, our obj ective is to stud y
whether the three roles of institutional investors di scussed abo ve indeed play a signific ant role in
corporate spin-offs. To achieve this, we analyze the post-spin-off institutional trading imbalance (i.e. the
5 For example, regarding the spin-off of Viacom from CBS, an article in The New York Times (December 26, 2005)
pointed out that “Viacom is to continue to build its portfolio of cable channels overseas…That strategy is aimed at
highlighting the fast-growing cable network business. Meanwhile, CBS is taking steps to make its stock more
attractive to value investors, those who seek reliable income and dividends rather than rapid growth.”
Page 6
relative difference in the direction and magnitude of an institution’s trading in the equity of the post-spin-
off parent and subsidiary arising from the same conglomerate firm). We analyze this trading imbalance to
test three dif ferent hypotheses regarding the inform ation production, pure pla y, and risk manage ment
roles of institutional investors in spin-offs. In the second part of the paper, we exam ine the information
production role of institutional investors in further detail by analyzing the predictive power of institutional
trading around corporate s pin-offs for the short-term stock return (announcement effect) and the l ong-
term stock return following spin-offs. In the third part of the paper, we study the pattern and profitability
of institutional trading in the spun-off subsidiaries following spin-offs, which will shed further light on
whether institutional investors are able to realize abnormal profits from any information advantage they
may have from corporate spin-offs.
Our paper documents a number of results on the role of institutional investors around corpor ate
spin-offs, for the first ti me in the literature. These can be summari zed as follows. Our first set of result s
deals with institutional trading im balance: we find a significant im balance in post-spin-off institutional
trading between parents and subsidiaries. Thus, in the first three months immediately following the spin-
off com pletion, o ver 46 % of the trading by insti tutions in po st-spin-off p arent-subsidiary pairs was
originated in opposite dir ections (buy versus sell). Even for trading in t he same direction, institutions
concentrated their trading heavily in one division (parent or subsidiary) rather than trading symmetrically
in both divisions (see figure 1). We inte rpret this significant trading imbalance as evidence that spin-offs
improve institutional investors’ trading welfare by relaxing a trading constraint existing prior to the spin-
off. Further, we find that this imbalance incr eases corresponding to t he difference in inform ation
asymmetry between the post-spin-off parent and subs idiary, i.e. instituti onal investors bought m ore
equity in the post-spin-off division facing a hi gher extent of i nformation asymmetry. We al so find that
this imbalance increases corresponding to the difference in beta risk between parent and subsidiary, i.e.
sample institutional in vestors bought more equit y in the post-spin-off division with hig her market risk.
Finally, we f ind that this trading imbalance is pos itively related to the differe nce in long-t erm growth
rates between parent and subsidiar y, as well as to th e difference in expected profitability between these
Page 7
two division s. Overall, the above results on institutional tradi ng im balance support t he notion that
institutional investors play an inform ation production, a risk m anagement, and a pure pla y role around
corporate spin-offs.
Our second set of results deals with the predictive power of institutional trading around corporate
spin-offs. First, institutional trading in the combined firm two months prior to the spin-off has significant
predictive power for the announcem ent effect of a spin-off. Second, institutional trading in the spun-off
subsidiary immediately after spin-off com pletion also has predictive power for its subsequent long-term
stock returns. This predic tive power i s greater wh en the subsi diary’s size constitutes onl y a sm aller
fraction of the combined (pre-spin-off) firm’s size (see figure 2). Third, institutional trading in the parent
firm also has predictive p ower for its subsequent long-term stock returns, b ut this predictive power is
weaker than in the case of a subsidiary. Overall, the above results indicate that institutional investors have
considerable private infor mation about firms undergoi ng spin-offs, and pro vide further su pport for the
information production role of institutional investors around spin-offs.
Our third set of results deals with the pattern and profitability of institutional trading in the
subsidiary firm’s equity after spin-off com pletion. We separate institutional post-spin-off trading in the
subsidiary in to two categories: pure post-spin-off trading (i .e. bu ying and selling of t he spun-off
subsidiary’s stock by inst itutions in the secondary market after the spin-off ) and institut ional share
allocation sales (i.e. sales of subsidiary shares obtained through the pro-rata distribution in spin-offs by
institutional investors).6 We document that institutional investors ar e able to realize superior profits b y
trading in the equity of the subsidiary in the secondary market during the first q uarter after the spin-off.
Further, institutional investors’ trading profit in the post-spin-off subsidiary declines over time, which
suggests that their inform ation advantage in spin-offs is mostly confined to the immediate post-spin-off
6 Given that the post-spin-off parent takes on the identity of the combined firm, it is difficult to cleanly identify the
point in time at which the parent shares were acquired by institutions. Therefore, cleanly separating out institutional
share allocation sales from pure post-spin-off trading, and, consequently, analyzing the profitability of institutional
trading in the parent becomes problematic. On the other hand, given that th e equity of th e spun-off subsidiary is
listed independently only after th e spin-off, we are ab le to easily separate institutional share allocation sales from
pure post-spin-off trading in the subsidiary firms’ shares. We will, therefore, confine our empirical analysis of the
pattern and profitability of post-spin-off institutional trading to the subsidiary alone.
Page 8
period. Of the total allocation sales of subsidiary shares by institutional investors in the first y ear post-
spin-off, 70% occurs wit hin the first quarter after th e spin-off. Further, we find that allocation sales of
shares soon after the spin-off are significantly less profitable than sales of shar es held longer ter m. Our
allocation sales results suggest that institutional invest ors sell off subsidiary shares allocated to them in a
spin-off soon after the spin-off distribution when they do not have favorable private information about the
subsidiary’s shares, while holding s hares of fir ms regarding which they have favo rable private
information for a longer investment horizon.
What do our results tell us overall about the role of institutional investors in spin-offs? First, we
confirm that institutions indeed have an information advantage over ret ail investors regarding the future
prospects of the firm s involved in a spin-off. Further, this inform ation advantage i s greater for
subsidiaries compared to that for parent fir ms; smaller the subsidiary as a fraction of the pre-spin-off
(combined) firm, greater this information advantage. Second, our results indicate that spin-offs do indeed
relax a trading constraint existing prior to t he spin-off on institutional investors. Further, we show that
institutions take advantage of the a bove relaxation of their trading constr aint by trading differently in the
parent and subsidiary. these trading differences seem to be m otivated eit her by differences in the
information advantage institutions have with respect to the p arent versus that with respect to th e
subsidiary, or due to othe r differences between the parent and subsid iary such as risk or future growth
prospects. Finally, we show that institutions are able to realize short-term abnormal profits by trading in
the secondary market in the equit y of the subsidiary firm immediately after spin-off completion. Overall,
our results are consistent with institutions be nefiting signifi cantly from corporate spin-offs and
consequently motivating the management of undervalued firms to undertake such spin-offs.
Our paper is related to several strands in the literature. As discussed before, the theoretical papers
most closely related to this paper are those which develop a rationale for spin-offs based on how spin-offs
reduce the extent of asymmetric information between firm insiders and outsiders: see e.g. Chemmanur
Page 9
and Liu (200 5), Habib, Johnsen, and Naik (1997), and Nanda and Naray anan (1999).7 A number o f
empirical studies on corporate spin-offs have focused on value increases arising from spin-offs and have
documented positive announcement eff ects, positive a bnormal long-term stock returns, and increased
operating performance, respectively. following corporate spin-offs: see, e.g. Hite and Owers (1983),
Schipper and Smith (1983), and Miles and Rosenfeld (1983)) on announcement effects; Cusatis, Miles,
and Woolridge (1993) on long-term stock returns; and Desai and Jain (1999), and Daley. Mehrotra, and
Sivakumar (1997) on long-term operating performance. Chemmanur and Nandy (2003) document that the
efficiency of the plants constituting a firm i mproves on average following corporate spin-offs, and
identify the precise sourc es of these e fficiency improvements. Gilson, Healy, Noe, and Pa lepu (2001)
empirically document that there is an increas e in analyst coverage of firms following spin-offs and other
stock break-ups. A number of papers have tested alternative theories of corporate spin-offs: see, e.g. Ahn
and Denis (2 004), Dittmar and Shivdasani (2003), Burch and Nanda (2003), and Krishnaswami and
Subramaniam (1999). There is also a significant literatu re on the capital structure of post-spin-off firms:
see, e.g. Par rino (1997) and Ditt mar (2004). Fina lly, McConnell, Ozbilgin, and Wahal (2001) have
studied the long-term profitability of investing in the equity of spin-off firms.8, 9
The remainder of this paper is organized as fo llows: Section 2 summarizes the underlying theory
and develops testable hypotheses; Secti on 3 describes the data and m easures of institutional trading that
we use in our e mpirical analy sis; Section 4 presents the algorithm that we use for s eparating out
subsidiary share allocation sales from pure post-spin-off trading in the subsidiary ; Section 5 presents our
empirical tests and discusses results; and Section 6 concludes.
7 There are several other theoretical models of spin-offs based on considerations other than asymmetric information:
see, e.g. Aron (1991), and Chemmanur and Yan (2004).
8 Our paper is also related to the extensive literature on the role of institutional investors around various corporate
events: Chemmanur, He, and Hu (2005), and Gibson, Safieddine, and Sonti (2004) study the role of institutional
investors around SEOs; Ch emmanur and Hu (2005) study the role of institutional investors in IPOs; Gillan and
Starks ( 2003), C ornett et al (2 005) a nd a n umber o f other em pirical pape rs st udy t he rel ationship between
institutional ownership and firm performance.
9 Ab arbanell e t al (2 003) ex amine t he p ost-spin-off p rice pre ssure ca used by t he n oninformational t rades by
institutions driven by portfolio rebalancing needs. They, however, do not analyze the role of institutional investors in
corporate spin-offs.
Page 10
2. Theory and Hypothesis
In this sectio n, we will br iefly summarize the relevant theory and develop hypotheses for our
empirical tests.
Chemmanur and Liu (2005) m odel how spin-offs can potentially lead to an increase in
information production by institutional investors and their affiliated analysts about each of t he divisions
constituting a pre-spin-off co mbined firm. In their model, there are two types of institutional investors
who can produce information about a conglom erate firm with two divisions, A and B. Type 1 investors
have expertise (lower inform ation production cost) for producin g information about divis ion A of the
combined firm and a significantly higher cost of producing information about division B; conversely, type
2 investors have expertise only for producing information about division B and a significantly higher cost
of producing information about division A. Prior to the spin-off, type 1 institutional investors producing
information about division A and trading in the combin ed firm’s stock using this information are subject
to considerable “noise” arising from their lack of precise information about division B. This noise reduces
type 1 institutional investors’ expected profit fro m producing i nformation about division A of the pre-
spin-off firm. Similarly, type 2 i nvestors’ lack of precise information about division A reduces their
expected profit from producing information about division B of the combined firm. Spin-offs reduce the
above “noise” by allowing each institu tional investor to concentrate his investment only on the stock o f
the firm (division) about which he ha s private info rmation, thus increasing hi s expected profit and,
therefore, his incentive to produce information about that division. This means that spin-offs increase
information production about both divisions relative to the level of information production existing prior
to the spin-off. Fro m now onwards, we will refe r to the above hypothesis as th e information production
hypothesis.10
10 In developing hypotheses related to information production, we rely primarily on t he theoretical analysis by
Chemmanur and Liu (2005). This is because, while other models like Nanda and Narayanan (1999) and Habib,
Johnsen, and Naik (1997) have also argued that spin-offs improve firm value by reducing information asymmetry
between firm insiders and outsiders, the latter papers do not model information production by outsiders around
corporate spin-offs.
Page 11
The inform ation pr oduction h ypothesis generate s several testable predictions. The first
predication is that, while some institutional investors will have private information only about the parent,
others will have private information only about the subsidiary. Therefore, institutional investors trading in
the subsidiary will be different from those trading in the parent firm. In other words, a given institutional
investor will trade predominantly either in the parent or in the subsidiary, but not in both: i.e. there will
be an institutional “trading imbalance”. This is the first hypothesis we test in this paper:
H1 (Institutional Trading Imbalance): Upon the separation of the parent and subsidiary firm, there will be
a significant i mbalance in post-spin-off institutional trading between the eq uity of t he parent and the
subsidiary.11
The information production hypothesis suggests that institutional investors will choose to trade in
such a way as to maximize their expected profit from trading on their private information. This means that
they will choose to trade i n those spin-off stocks (either parent or subsidiar y) where their inform ation
advantage relative to ordinary (uninformed) investors is the greatest. Further, since, under the information
production hypothesis, institutional investors have greater expertise in producing information (i.e. greater
informational advantage with respect to ord inary investors) about one of the two div isions (firms)
resulting from a spin-off, the extent of the institutional trading imbalance will be greater as the difference
in information asymmetry between the parent and subs idiary involved in a sp ecific spin-off is greater.
This is the next hypothesis we test here:
H2 (Institutional Trading Imbalance and Information Asymmetry): The extent of the instituti onal trading
imbalance between the divisions in a spin-off will increase corresponding to the differences in the extent
of information asymmetry faced by (uninformed) investors in the equity of these divisions.
Institutional trading imbalance may also arise due to reasons other than private information on the
part of institutional investors. For example, as discussed in the previous section, the desire of institutional
11 If an institution continues to trade in the parent and subsidiary in the proportion of their shares outstanding after
the spin-off, we refer to this trading as “balanced.” Institutional trading imbalance measures the deviation from such
balanced trading. We will discuss in detail the construction of our measures of institutional trading imbalance in
section 3.3.
Page 12
investors such as mutual funds to better manage the risk of their own portfolios (“risk management”) may
also generate institutional trading imbalance, since institutions desiring to hold equity in high-risk firms
would buy additional equity in the high-risk division of the conglomerate firm immediately after the spin-
off, while selling off t he equity in the low-risk division (that they may have been allocated by virtue of
their share h oldings in th e pre-spin-off conglom erate firm); conversely, managers of low-risk mutual
funds may buy additional stock in the low-risk divisi on after the spin-off, while selling off equit y in the
high-risk division. This gives rise to the following testable hypothesis:
H3 (Institutional Trading Imbalance and Risk Management): The institutiona l trading im balance will
increase corresponding to the difference in risk between parent and subsidiary.
Finally, institutional trading imbalance may also arise due to the desire of inst itutional investors
such as mutual funds to make pure play investments in the equity of the individual firms resulting from a
spin-off. For example, growth funds can invest in the high-growth divisions and value funds can invest in
the lower growth but undervalued divisions (which may generate more r eliable cash flows) of a
conglomerate firm after a spin-off. Since many U.S. mutual funds are marketed to investors as “growth
funds” or “value funds”, splitting conglomerates into pure play companies can make the shares of the
resulting firms more attractive to these funds, increasing demand for the shares of both parent and
subsidiary. This gives rise to the following testable hypothesis:
H4 (Institutional Trading Imbalance and Pure Play Investment): The institutional trading imbalance will
increase corresponding to the difference in growth rates between parent and subsidiary.
The information prod uction hypothesis also has t estable implications regarding the information
content of institutional trading around corporate spin-offs. First, since the theory predicts that institutional
investors will have an informational advantage over ordinary (uninformed) investors about the parent and
subsidiary following a spi n-off, institutional trading around a spin-off will have predictive power for
future stock returns both in the short run (announcement effect of the combined firm) and in the long run
(the long-run post-spin-off returns of parent and subsidiary).
Page 13
H5 (Predictive Power for the Announcement Effect): Trading by institutional investors with privat e
information will have predictive power for the announcement effect of a spin-off.
H6 (Predictive Power for Long-run Stock Returns): Trading by institut ional investors with private
information will have predictive power for the long-ter m post-spin-off stock returns of the subsidiary and
of the parent.
Second, the information production hypothesis predicts that, the smaller the spun-off division as a
fraction of the combined firm, the greater the increase in information production by institutional investors
about that division due to the spin-off. This implies that institutional trading in a smaller subsidiar y (or
parent) will have greater predictive power for the fut ure stock returns of that subsidiary (or parent). This
gives rise to the following testable prediction:
H7 (Predictive Power and the Relative Size of a Spun-off Division): The s maller the subsidiary (or
parent) as a fraction of the combined firm, the greater the predictive power of institutional trading for the
future stock returns from that firm.
The information production theor y also genera tes two testable hypotheses regarding t he pattern
and profitability of institutional trading around corporate spin-offs. First, if institutional investors have an
informational advantage over retail investors about the subsidiary firm’s future performance, this will be
reflected in t he realized profitabilit y of their post- spin-off tradi ng, since one would expect them to
generate superior profits from such informed trading. This gives rise to the following testable hypothesis:
H8 (Profitability of Post-Spin-off Institutional Trading): Institutional investors will be able t o generate
superior profits by trading in the subsidiary around the spin-off.
Second, assuming that their private information is about the long ter m performance of the fir m,
institutional investors will sell the equity in spun-off firms about which they either do not have private
information (or have unfavorable information) soon after the spin-off distribution, while holding equity in
firms about which they have favorable private in formation longer (to be sold after their private
information is publicly realized, and incorporated in to stock prices). This gi ves rise to t he following
testable hypothesis:
Page 14
H9 (Profitability of Institutional Allocation Sales): Institutions will make superior profits on the sales of
shares in spun-off subsidi aries held for a longer inv estment horizon relative to those held f or a shorter
horizon.
3. Data and Measures of Institutional Trading
In this section, we describe the data and sa mple selection procedures, and construct measures of
institutional trading. Section 3.1 describes the spin-off sample and presents descriptive statistics. Section
3.2 describes the institutional trading sample and presents descriptive statistics. Section 3.3 describes the
construction of various institutional trading measures used in our empirical analysis.
3.1. Spin-off Sample
Our spin-off sam ple covers spin-offs which have a distributi on between January 1 999 and
December 2004. Our sample is obtained from three sources. We first obtain all the spin-offs listed in the
Securities Data Co mpany’s (SDC) mergers and a cquisitions database. S eparately, we us e the C RSP
database to identify all distribution events during the period with distribution codes starting with 37. The
two sources provide the initial sam ple of spin-offs. We then use FACTIVA news search to further verify
the character istics of these spin-offs, and to obtain additional inform ation such as the spin-off
announcement date. Following the spin-off literature, we focus our sample on tax-free spin-offs where the
parents control at lea st 80% of the share interests in the subsidiaries before t he distribution. We also
delete fro m our sam ple equit y carve-outs, two-stage spin-offs, merger motivated spin-of fs, spin-offs
where tracking stocks for the spun-o ff units already existed, spin-offs that are ADRs, sp in-offs with
concurrent security offerings, and spin-offs of close-end funds and REITs. The spin-off parents and
subsidiaries also need to be covered by the CRSP and COMPUSTAT database in order to be included in
our final sample. This procedure results in a total of 66 spin-off events.12
12 In four events, the parents had simultaneous distributions of two independent subsidiaries, instead of one. Two
parents had follow-on spin-offs which were part of the restructuring plan that were announced at the same time as
the first spin-off distributions. We exclude these follow-on distributions in our sample.
Page 15
Table 1 provides the pattern of spin-off events over the six years covered by our sample, and the
descriptive s tatistics of the spin -off co mpanies b efore and af ter spin-off co mpletion. The y early
occurrence of spin-off events during this sample period is generally higher than that reported in previous
studies on spin-offs.13 Of the 66 spin-off parents prior to the distribution, sample institutions actively
engaged in t he trading of 56 firm s during the peri od starting fr om three months prior to the spin-off
announcement to the day before the spin-off distribution. Not reported in the table, the 10 firms not traded
by sample institutions are smaller, with lower market-to-book ratio and lower return-on-assets than the 56
traded firms. Similarly, the post-spin-off entities that retained such characteristics are also not traded by
sample institutions. The characteristics of these firms suggest that sample institutions may choose not to
actively trade the equities of these firms primarily out of regulatory and liquidity concerns.
For the firm characteristic descriptions provided in Table 1, other than the ma rket capitalization
that is measured on the day of the spin-off distributi on, all other pre-spin-off data are based on end-of-
fiscal-year information from COMPUSTAT and IBES prio r to the spin-off distribution, while the post-
spin-off data are based on the information available at the end of the first fisc al year following the spin-
off distribution. Market capitalization of the p ost-spin-off parent and subsidiary equals the closing price
of the firm’s shares times the total number of sh ares outstanding at the spin-off distribution date.
14 The
sum of the market capitalization of the parent and subsidiary is the market capitalization of the pre-spin-
off combined firm. Spun-off subsidiaries are in general smaller than their parents. On average, our sample
post-spin-off parents are about three times the size of their subsidiaries, based on book assets or on market
capitalization; this is si milar to that reported in previous studies on spin-offs. The market-to-book ratio
and return-on-assets ratio of parents are also generally higher than those of subsidiaries, both in terms of
13 For example, there are a total of 146 pure spin-offs during the 1965-1988 period reported in Cusatis, Miles, and
Woolridge (1993). Similarly, during the 1979-1996 period there are 106 spin-off events by 95 parents reported in
Burch and Nanda (2003). This comes out to about six spin-off events per year. The occurrence of spin-off events per
year almost doubled during our sample period compared with the early years, reflecting the increased level of spin-
off activity in recent years.
14 When the distribution is after market close, the next trading day is the first day that parent and subsidiary begin
their separate listings. In these cases, we treat the effective distribution date as the next trading day.