For Better or Worse Mutual Funds in SideBySide Management Relationships With Hedge Funds
Post on: 10 Июль, 2015 No Comment
Page 1
For Better or Worse? Mutual Funds in
Side-by-Side Management Relationships with Hedge Funds
We are grateful to Gordon Alexander, Vladimir Atanasov, Roger Edelen, Pedro Matos, John
Merrick, John Rea, Jonathan Reuter, Erik Sirri, Sheridan Titman, Lori Walsh, and participants at
the Frank Batten Young Scholars Conference 2006 and Western Finance Association 2006 for
Abstract
Firms that engage in the simultaneous, or “side-by-side”, management of mutual funds and hedge
funds have a fiduciary duty to each fund’s investors to make portfolio decisions and to execute
such favoritism. The reported returns of side-by-side mutual funds are significantly less than
those of similar mutual funds run by firms that do not also manage hedge funds. A
decomposition of reported returns into holdings-return and return-gap components and return-
persistence tests also suggest favoritism. Finally, examining a potential wealth transference
mechanism, we find evidence consistent with side-by-side mutual funds getting less of a
contribution to performance from IPO underpricing than matched unaffiliated mutual funds.
Page 3
Delegated portfolio management firms that run multiple funds have a fiduciary duty to
each fund’s investors to make portfolio decisions and to execute trades in the most favorable way.
This fiduciary duty is put to the test, however, when management firms can increase fee income
by treating fund investors inequitably. Consistent with the implementation of such strategies,
Gasper, Massa, and Matos (2006) provide evidence suggesting that mutual fund families sought
to increase fee income by strategically transferring performance across member funds.
Specifically, strategies favored high-fee funds or younger-aged and high-performing funds best
positioned to take advantage of the convex flow-return relation.1 Of course, this increased
performance came at the expense of other mutual fund investors.
In this paper, we examine another setting where delegated portfolio management firms
have incentives to strategically transfer performance across the funds they oversee. We examine
firms that engage in the simultaneous, or “side-by-side”, management of mutual funds and hedge
funds. Given the structural differences in fees between mutual funds and hedge funds, one might
expect management firms’ incentives to transfer performance from mutual funds to hedge funds
to be at least as great as across mutual fund family members. In contrast to mutual funds that
charge fees based on a fixed percentage of assets under management, hedge funds typically levy
additional performance-based fees equal to 20% or more of realized capital gains and capital
appreciation. The resulting incentives for management firms to strategically transfer performance
to hedge funds from mutual funds has attracted the attention of the U.S. Securities and Exchange
Commission (SEC), which has expressed concern about the welfare of mutual fund investors in
side-by-side arrangements with hedge funds.2 Our study investigates whether these concerns are
justified.
1 Chevalier and Ellison (1997) and Sirri and Tufano (1998), among others, find that investor inflows are
more sensitive to top performing funds versus lower performing funds. Chevalier and Ellison (1997) show
that the convex flow-return relation is particularly strong for young funds.
2 U.S. Securities and Exchange Commission (September 2003) articulates these concerns.
Page 4
Management firm favoritism that transfers performance from mutual funds to hedge
funds can take many forms. We list six examples: First, management firms can front run the
execution of hedge fund trades ahead of mutual fund trades.3 Second, in a practice known as
‘cherry-picking’, decisions about how a trade is allocated can be delayed, with trades
experiencing favorable subsequent price movements allocated to hedge funds. Third, rather than
allocating the average price paid in a bunched trade, shares bought at the lowest price and shares
sold at the highest price can be allocated to hedge funds. Fourth, mutual funds can pay trade
commissions inflated by soft dollar payments, but hedge funds can benefit from services
purchased with the soft dollars.4 Fifth, management firms can allocate disproportionately more
underpriced IPO shares to hedge funds and fewer to mutual funds. In the sixth and final example,
the favoritism is quid pro quo: For hedge fund investors who agree to commit assets for extended
periods, management firms extend market timing or late trading privileges in the mutual funds
they oversee.5 In this last example, the wealth transference may be more circuitous than in the
other examples, but the end result is that hedge fund investors’ market-timing or late-trading
profits come at mutual fund investors’ expense.6
Direct empirical detection of these acts of favoritism using transactions level data is
impossible for us given that the data is not publicly available.7 Thus we conduct a number of
3 In conversations with industry practitioners, we learned that at least some management firms distribute
stock “hot lists” to mutual fund and hedge fund managers. The stocks that appear on these hot lists are the
best picks generated by the management firm’s research group. If management firms favor hedge funds
over mutual funds in the order filling process, reported mutual fund holdings will not reflect the most
recent valuation beliefs. Moreover, if the management firm’s trades move stock prices, then hedge funds
will transact at better prices than mutual funds. In this scenario, mutual fund holdings returns will thus be
negatively affected.
4 Greenwich Associates (2006) reports that in 2004, about 75% of mutual funds paid trade commissions
that were inflated by soft dollar payments. In 2005, more than 60% of U.S. management firms that used
soft dollars indicated that other departments within the firm benefited from services paid with equity trades.
5 The SEC’s case against Alliance Capital, discussed later, is a specific example of such favoritism.
6 Zitzewitz (2003) estimates around $5 billion annual losses for long-term mutual fund investors due to
market timing. Zitzewitz (2006) finds significant evidence of late trading behavior in 39 out of 66 mutual
fund families in his sample, and suggests that many of those families were aware of such illegal behavior in
their funds. He estimates annual mutual fund investor losses at about $400 million due to late trading.
7 Recognize that if direct detection was possible, litigation concerns would likely dissuade side-by-side
management firms from such acts.
Page 5
empirical tests that rely on indirect evidence of favoritism. Our first set of empirical tests is based
on the premise that all of the above acts of favoritism negatively affect the performance of the
mutual funds in the side-by-side arrangement. If side-by-side management firms engage in
strategies that transfer wealth, then side-by-side mutual funds ought to exhibit returns that
underperform those of similar unaffiliated mutual funds (i.e. those run by management firms that
do not also run hedge funds).
In addition to examining reported returns, we examine holdings returns, calculated as the
buy-and-hold return on a portfolio comprised of the most recently disclosed securities, and return
gaps, defined as reported returns less holdings returns.8 Acts of favoritism that occur between
holdings reporting intervals, such as front running, cherry picking, unbalanced bunched trade
allocations, inequitable commission and soft dollar allocations, preferential IPO allocations,
market timing, and late trading, affect reported mutual fund returns but not holdings returns.
Thus, return gaps capture the impact of these unobserved short-term acts of favoritism on mutual
fund returns. Although holdings returns are not affected by these short-term acts, holdings
returns may be negatively affected if hedge funds are prioritized when moving into or out of
illiquid positions, resulting in mutual fund reported holdings not reflecting the most recent
valuation beliefs.9
We also consider the possibility that policies designed to protect side-by-side mutual fund
investors from conflicts of interest differ considerably across management firms. Strong
protections contribute to evenhanded treatment in portfolio decisions and trade execution,
8 Studies that examine actual mutual fund returns and holdings returns include Grinblatt and Titman (1989);
Wermers (2000); Frank, Poterba, Shackelford, and Shoven (2004); Meier and Schaumburg (2005); and