Rebels Conformists Contrarians And Momentum Traders
Post on: 16 Март, 2015 No Comment
Page 3
2Brennan and Cao (1996) have demonstrated that asymmetric information may lead to
rational momentum trading when information is revealed gradually in the market.
In a noisy capital market with imperfect information, there is room for rational agents
with heterogenous beliefs. In this paper we compare the optimal portfolio strategies of two
types of agents – conformists who believe in the log-normal market consensus and “rebels”
whose alternative beliefs incorporate price predictability. Surprisingly, we find that
momentum trading is optimal for rebels who believe that the market is grossly mispriced.
The empirical work of Lakonishok, Shleifer and Vishny (1994), Jegadeesh and Titman
(1993) and Gatev, Goetzmann and Rouwenhorst (1999) documents profits from momentum
and contrarian strategies that appear to exploit predictable price movements. These profits
raise the question whether such momentum and contrarian strategies are, in fact, the optimal
trading strategies of agents who incorporate price predictability in their alternative beliefs
about the market process. The main contribution of our paper is to enable the empirical
detection of non-conformist beliefs about the possibility of market timing.
Recent papers like DeLong et al. (1990), Barberis et al. (1997) and Hong and Stein
(1999) merely postulate the existence of irrational agents who behave as momentum traders.
However, alternative beliefs need not be irrational – Merton (1980), Summers (1986) and
Poterba and Summers (1989) have argued that it is extremely difficult to distinguish
statistically between randomness and certain forms of price-predictability.
Alternative specifications of the price process were explored in the early work of Merton
(1971) who showed that an agent who believes in an exponential trend always invests more
We employ the Cox-Huang (1989) martingale approach to the terminal wealth portfolio
problem of the agent, to address a collection of issues about the optimal trading strategy
under the alternative beliefs that incorporate price predictability. What will the rebel do?
How well will the rebel do? Can we distinguish the rebel from the typical market
participant?
Our main results show that the rebels act as momentum traders when they believe that
the current market price is far from the “right” price. In contrast, the conformists are
contrarian or momentum traders depending on whether they are more or less risk averse than
the representative agent. Thus, to an outsider, risk-averse rebels whose beliefs are far from
the market’s beliefs may appear as risk-tolerant conformists. The terminal wealth
distribution of rebels whose beliefs are sufficiently different from those of the market are
first-order dominated by certain conformist portfolios. But, in general, the properties of the
terminal wealth distribution under different beliefs suggest that it is difficult to detect wrong
beliefs from limited performance data. Finally, the long-run investment portfolios of both
conformists and rebels need not be heavily biased towards equities. Both the conformist’s
and the rebel’s long-run portfolios include a positive equity component, however equities
need not dominate the portfolio.
Our conformist momentum results generalize and make empirically relevant the
qualitative momentum aspect of the early portfolio insurance work of Leland (1980) and
Brennan and Solanki (1981). Moreover, Leland (1980) considered the optimal portfolio
insurance for agents who have different estimates of the mean holding period return.
Our paper differs from Leland (1980) in two major ways. First, we define alternative
Our main objective is to enable the empirical detection of alternative beliefs in reversion
and the feasibility of market timing. Our dynamic specification of the beliefs in reversion
allows the investment opportunity set to depend on the current market conditions. Hence the
more general dynamic definition of alternative beliefs is necessary in order to capture beliefs
in the possibility of opportunistic market timing. We relate this alternative dynamic
specification to observable trading patterns. In contrast, Leland (1980) emphasizes that his
model does not allow for market timing, while the Brennan and Solanki (1981) model has no
differences in expectations. These models remain within the static log-normal specification,
and there are no perceived changes in the investment opportunity set. On the other hand, we
are able to solve for the more general dynamic beliefs by using the Cox-Huang methodology,
which was not available at the time of the earlier models. Our results explain observed
counter-intuitive momentum trading with deviant beliefs in market reversion to a growth
trend, while remaining within the attractive rational paradigm of utility-maximizing agents.
The wrong beliefs are maintained because of market noise that prevents the timely
unambiguous learning of the proper dynamic specification.
In section I we present the model. Section II analyzes the momentum and contrarian
appearance of the optimal trading for different beliefs about the market dynamics. In section
III we examine the performance of the strategies that are optimal under different beliefs.