The impact of trade and investment liberalization on the wage skill premium evidence from Vietnam
Post on: 31 Март, 2015 No Comment
The impact of trade and investment liberalization on
Kien Trung Nguyen
October 2014
Working Paper No. 2014/20
Arndt-Corden Department of Economics
Crawford School of Public Policy
ANU College of Asia and the Pacific
Page 2
Page 3
The impact of trade and investment liberalization on the
wage skill premium: evidence from Vietnam
Kien Trung Nguyen*
The Arndt-Corden Department of Economics
Crawford School of Public Policy
Australian National University
Email: kien.nguyen@anu.edu.au
* Acknowledgements: I am grateful to Prema-chandra Athukorala, Chris Manning, and Hal Hill for valuable
The impact of trade and investment liberalization on the
wage skill premium: evidence from Vietnam
Kien Trung Nguyen
The Arndt-Corden Department of Economics
Crawford School of Public Policy
Australian National University
Email: kien.nguyen@anu.edu.au
Abstract: This paper examines the impact of trade and investment liberalization on the wage
1. Introduction
The impact of an outward-oriented development strategy on wages remains a significant focus
in the ongoing debate about workers’ welfare in developing countries. Opening the market to
international trade and investment will affect the wage skill premium between skilled and
unskilled workers (herein forth referred as to the wage premium). However, there is no
unanimity in the theoretical literature on the impact of industrialization on the wage premium
in the manufacturing sector in developing countries. The Lewis-Fei-Ranis model1 does not
make a distinction between skilled and unskilled labour, but it implies that the wage premium
could continue to increase as long as surplus labour conditions prevail in the economy. The
standard Heckscher-Ohlin-Stolper-Samuelson (HOSS) theory predicts that in a labour-
abundant economy there will be a rise in manufacturing wages of unskilled workers
associated with an expansion in manufacturing exports. By contrast, the Feenstra-Hanson
extension (Feenstra & Hanson 1996) to the HOSS theory postulates that the engagement of
developing countries in global production sharing could result in increasing the wage
premium in manufacturing wages in these countries. This effect also rests on skill-biased
technological change, which accounts for the increased demand for skilled workers following
a rise in imports of capital goods and technology into the developing economies (Acemoglu
2003; Robbins 1996; Wood 1995).
Outward-oriented liberalization reforms in Vietnam since the early 2000s have
generated special interest in how the role of international trade and investment has affected
wage inequality in that country. In particular, these liberalization reforms of trade, investment
and enterprise policy regimes have intensified since 2006, and should have significant effects
on the wages of unskilled workers, where Vietnam’s comparative advantage lies. Given the
nature of these outward-oriented reforms, Vietnam provides an ideal case study of the wage
skill premium in the manufacturing sector.
Despite its importance in the debate on gains from global economic integration, the
issue of a wage premium has received little attention in the studies on Vietnam. Although
Page 6
In this paper, we examine the determinants of the wage skill premium in relation to
trade and investment liberalization in the Vietnamese manufacturing sector using a firm-level
dataset derived from the Vietnam’s Enterprise Surveys. The findings show that trade
liberalization, in particular reductions in tariffs on inputs, through its contribution to export
expansions and employment growth has served to reduce the wage premium in Vietnam. The
presence of foreign invested enterprises has contributed to an increase in the wage premium.
These findings make a significant contribution to the ongoing debate in the literature on
whether and how trade liberalization affects wages and inequality in developing countries.
The structure of the paper is as follows. Section 2 surveys the empirical evidence of the
wage premium following outward-oriented liberalization in developing countries. Section 3
establishes a model relating a wage premium to tariff variations and firm ownership in order
to determine the wage premium using a cross-section of firm-level data. Section 4 discusses
data compilation and econometric method. Section 5 presents and discusses the estimation
results. As a comparison, the following section investigates determinants of average wage
rates. The final section provides concluding remarks on the significant effect that export-
oriented foreign investment has on the wage premium.
2. Trade and investment liberalization and wage skill premium: empirical issues
As with the theoretical literature, the findings of empirical studies remain inconclusive. There
is significant evidence to support the narrowing wage premium between skilled and unskilled
workers in labour-abundant economies in East Asia following export-oriented
industrialization. Throughout the 1960s-1970s export expansion narrows the wage premium
in East Asian economies (Galenson 1992; Kim & Topel 1995; Kuo 1989; Wood 1997). In
Taiwanese manufacturing, the wage inequality between white-collar employees and blue-
collar ones reduced over the process of industrialization (Kuo 1989). Similarly, a reduction in
Page 7
Foreign investment coupled with technological advances is also important for affecting the
relative demand for skilled workers, and has with mixed effects on the wage premium. There
is evidence of a widening of the wage premium resulting from foreign investment and
technical change in Mexico’s maquiladoras (Feenstra & Hanson 1997; 1999) while the
opposite has been observed in Indonesia (Suryahadi, Chen & Tyers 2001). In this country, the
relative demand for unskilled labour rose while the wages of unskilled relative to skilled
workers decreased in the manufacturing over the period 1970s-1980s following the trade
reform. The Indonesia’s finding appears consistent with the prediction of the trade models;
whereas, contrary to Feenstra and Hanson (1996), foreign participation raised the relative
demand for unskilled workers.
Despite its prominence in empirical works, the impact of trade and investment
liberalization on the wage premium still remains a sparsely research subject of a Vietnam case
study. Gallup (2004) examines the wage inequality in Vietnam over the 1990s using two
rounds of the Vietnam Living Standards Survey (VLSS) between 1992/93 and 1997/98.
Employing the same rounds of household-level dataset, Liu (2004) investigates the changing
wage structure following the economic reform, focusing on gender wage gap and the overall
wage inequality between skilled and unskilled workers. Both these studies suggest a moderate
decline in wage inequality between these two time points, however, they do not take the
specific characteristics of trade and investment liberalization into account such as firm
ownership or tariff reduction.
The study by Fukase (2013) explores the two rounds of Vietnam Household Living
Standards Survey (VHLSS) in 2002 and 2004 in order to examine the wage premium in the
aftermath of the 2001 Bilateral Trade Agreement (BTA) with United States. In this study,
potential endogeneity of export intensity is addressed by using the province-tariff reduction as
an instrument. The findings show that increasing exports lead to growth in wages of unskilled
workers in those provinces that experience more exposure to trade liberalization. This rise in
wages is consistent with the East Asian economies in the process of export-oriented
industrialization. A major limitation of this study is that it examines the impact of only a
single trade agreement on industrial wages, without appropriately controlling for the impact of
comprehensive trade and investment liberalization in the overall economy during the same
period. Another limitation is that the study does not explore determinants of inter-industry
variations in wages, which is important for assessing the wage outcome of the
industrialization process.
3. Empirical model
There has been an increased interest in addressing the impact of international trade and
investment on the wage premium in firm heterogeneity models (Goldberg & Pavcnik 2007).
The Melitz model of firm heterogeneity and international trade (Melitz 2003) proposes that
the labour market outcomes of trade mainly rely on the degree to which the firm is involved
with globalization.2 Recently, a study by Amiti and Davis (2011) explores a Melitz-type
model with an incorporation of a fair wage approach (Egger & Kreickemeier 2009) and
establishes a link between firm heterogeneity and the wage premium. Their key proposition is
that large productive firms that tend to be involved with exporting and importing are likely to
Page 9
The dependent variable (Ws/Wu) is the wage premium which in turn is the ratio of an average
wage of skilled workers to that of unskilled workers. As is standard in many previous studies
(Hanson & Harrison 1999; Pavcnik et al. 2004), non-production workers are a proxy for
skilled labour and similarly, production workers for unskilled labour. Then, the ratio of the
average wage of non-production workers (white-collar) and production workers (blue-collar)
is used as a measure of the wage premium. Although the white-collar/blue-collar
classification does not capture perfectly skill levels measured by education attainment, the
usage of either measure as a dependent variable on the wage premium model brings about
comparable results in many empirical studies (Krueger 1997; Slaughter 2000).
In this analysis, the prime explanatory variables are tariffs, ownership dummies, and
export orientation. First, tariff variables are used to examine the effect of trade liberalization
on the wage premium. Both input (IT) and output tariffs (OT) are incorporated separately
because a firm’s wage outcome for a specific tariff reduction depends on whether the firm has
been involved in exporting or importing (Bernard et al. 2007). The reduction in output tariffs
in a developing country will increase wages in export firms that have a higher proportion of
unskilled workers. Meanwhile, it will reduce wages in import substitution firms, resulting in a
decline in the wage premium. Put simply, these effects of output tariff reductions are in line
with the standard HOSS trade theory. In a similar manner, a lower input tariff will affect
wages in firms that depend on intermediate inputs because of their lower prices relative to
those of domestically produced inputs. Given the higher skill-intensive production of
intermediate inputs relative to those of final product production in the developing world,
reducing input tariffs is likely to increase an import of intermediate inputs. As a result, firms
will reallocate resources to higher unskilled-intensive production that helps to narrow the
wage premium. They also will lay off skilled workers, reducing the wage premium.
Moreover, the inclusion of the input tariff is very much relevant to the labour-abundant
identify a significant difference in wages among three investment forms of FIEs in
Vietnamese manufacturing. Thus, it is important to include these three dummies, rather than
one foreign ownership dummy in this analysis of the wage premium in Vietnam. This is
because FIEs generally have a tendency to employ more skilled workers in Asian developing
economies (Lipsey 2004; Lipsey & Sjöholm 2004; Ramstetter 2004; Ramstetter & Sjöholm
2006).
Aside from the firm ownership feature, the vector Z in Equation (1) controls for other
firm characteristics. Based on the increasingly important role of firm-heterogeneity (Melitz
2003), several firm-specific factors are incorporated in the model. These include real output
(RQ), capital intensity (KL), gender ratio (GR), and skill share (SS).
In addition to firm specific factors, two additional vectors are included. The first one is
a variable (REG) presenting regional feature. Generally, capital-intensive industries are likely
to be concentrated in a region with a high level of economic development, leading to the
expansion of the relative demand for skilled workers in that region. Accordingly, the wage
premium will increase. As suggested by the geographic pattern of wages, three regional
dummies for the Red River Delta, the South East Area and the rest of Vietnam (a base
dummy) are employed. In addition to the regional effects, a variable (INS) of 21 industry
dummies at the two-digit VSIC level is incorporated to capture specific-industry effects. This
controls for the possible differences of the relative supply of skilled labour across industries
as well as other unobserved industry heteroskedasticity.
4. Data and variable construction
The main data in this study is the firm-level dataset compiled from the unpublished returns of
the Enterprise Surveys undertaken by the General Statistical Office of Vietnam (GSO).
Estimating this wage premium model using a panel dataset by pooling cross-firm and time-
series data is ideal, especially when our key interest is the wage premium. Unfortunately, this
preferred data is not available, given the nature of the Enterprise Surveys of Vietnam. To date,
there is only one Enterprise Survey of 2009 that has comprehensive information on
employment and wages by education and production – non-production workers. In that
Page 11
skilled labour. Production workers are treated as unskilled labour. Owing to the data on wages
classified by occupations, the wage bill used for examining the wage premium includes only
regular salary and other cash payments made to employees. In other words, wages do not
cover the employer’s contribution to social and health insurance funds.
With regard to demographic characteristics of workers, the data provide information on
gender, educational attainment, and occupation. Using the educational information on the
highest completed grade, skill share (SS) is measured as the proportion of the total workers
who completed tertiary education (college/university degree) in each firm. It is important to
note that this measurement of skill share may not totally match the ratio of non-production
and production workers. This is because some skilled workers are hidden in the production
worker category. (It would be preferable if wages could be broken down into categories by
educational attainment but this kind of data is not available). Finally, a gender ratio (GR) is
measured by the ratio of female to male workers.
The data from Enterprise Survey, which covers all registered formal firms, have been
cleaned and observations with non-positive values eliminated, along with outliers. For each
firm, the survey also provides information on gross output, and capital stock and profits. All
data in normal terms were converted to real term, using appropriate deflators. Additionally,
the dataset has four-digit industry classification codes (VSIC) consisting of 110
manufacturing industries that allow us to match industries with the tariff data. Note that many
small firms report implausible or unrealistic data due to their poor information and accounting
i=1
where tariffs are output tariff on the final product the four-digit
The weights aij are based on input coefficients from the Input-Output table (I-O table) of
2007, the latest I-O table in which comprehensive information on specific intermediate inputs
is available. Based on the concordance between I-O industry codes and industry classification
(VSIC) provided by GSO, we obtain the input tariff for each industry. Then, both the tariffs
Page 12
on final products and intermediate inputs are constructed at the four-digit VSIC level in order
to merge them with the firm-level data.
5. Results
This section presents the OLS estimation results to explore the determinants of the wage
premium. In order to control for any heteroskedasticity in the error terms, statistical
significance of the estimated coefficients is tested using standard errors based on the robust
variance-covariance matrix estimator (Wooldridge 2002). Summary statistics as well as a
correlation matrix of the variables are reported in Tables 2 and 3.
[Tables 2 and 3 around here]
The results for five alternative specifications are shown in Table 4. These specifications
are different from each other in the following features. The full model (Equation 1) is shown
in the first column, whereas the second column reports the specification excluding a skill
share variable. The third specification includes only a Red River Delta dummy, then the
fourth replaces that with the South East Area dummy. The specification without control of
industry dummies is presented in the last column.
[Table 4 around here]
A reduction in tariffs on intermediate inputs is likely to be associated with a narrowing
of the wage premium since the coefficients of input tariff (IT) are positive and significant at
conventional levels in most cases. Holding other factors unchanged, a ten-percentage point
reduction in input tariff is likely to result in a reduction of seven per cent in the wage
premium in the manufacturing sector. There is strong statistical evidence of an intra-industry
effect on the wage premium from lowering the input tariff. This finding is well in line with
Vietnam. As in our own analysis based on the I-O tables of Vietnam,6 a high proportion of
labour-intensive manufacturing exports in the Vietnamese economy over the period 2000-09
draws heavily on imported intermediate inputs which are viewed as more skilled labour-
intense. Lower input tariffs will stimulate a higher demand for imported inputs, leading to an
expansion in demand for unskilled workers in traditional labour-intensive industries such as
apparel, footwear, and furniture. For this effect, the wage premium is likely to decline.
Page 13
Next, lowering output tariffs also tends to narrow the wage premium. The positive sign
and significance of output tariff (OT) across various specifications implies that cutting output
tariffs tends to narrow the wage premium. The model predicts that a ten per cent fall in the
output tariff results in a three per cent decline in the wage inequality between skilled and
unskilled workers, holding other factors constant. This result is highly consistent with the
Heckscher-Ohlin trade model; opening up to international trade will cause each country to
specialize in industries that use the country’s most abundant factor more intensively. This
result is especially relevant in the case of the Vietnamese economy, where a massive pool of
unskilled workers has not been depleted. Trade liberalization adopted since the second half of
1990s has stimulated resources reallocation toward unskilled labour-intensive industries.
Consequently, export expansion resulting from the reduction and elimination of tariffs has
increased the price of unskilled labour-intensive goods, causing a rise in wages of unskilled
workers. All together, the significance of both tariffs implies a synergy in the effects of trade
liberalization on the wage premium.
In addition, export orientation appears to have widened the wage premium. The
coefficient of an export orientation (EO) is statistically insignificant in many cases, suggesting
that export orientation is less likely to be related to the wage premium. However, as shown in
Column 5, the coefficient on the EO variable is highly significant with a positive sign after
excluding two-digit industry dummies. Holding other effects constant, higher export
expansion is possibly associated with an increase in the wage premium between skilled and
unskilled labour. This finding runs counter to the prediction of the HOSS model but is
consistent with the abundance of unskilled labour in Vietnam. Export production in
Vietnamese manufacturing employs a large proportion of unskilled workers. As the country
has been abundant in unskilled labour,7 thus the wage premium can increase as implied by the
Lewis-Fei-Ranis model. Thus, there is the possibility that a rise in exports contributes to a
Page 14
consistent with the widely held proposition in the model of foreign investment and relative
wages (Feenstra & Hanson 1996; 1997).
Given the greater participation of FIEs in labour-intensive industries, it is likely that
export-oriented foreign investment, particularly wholly owned FIEs in export-oriented
manufacturing, has played a significant role in increasing the wage inequality between skilled
and unskilled labour. As revealed in trade orientation in Figure 1, joint ventures with private
firms and wholly owned FIEs tend to be concentrated on labour-intensive manufacturing for
exports, as above 40 per cent of their output in 2009 was in export-oriented manufacturing
industries. On the other hand, nearly 80 per cent of SOE total output is involved with
domestically oriented industries. Within export-oriented manufacturing, one half of
employment has been attributed to the wholly-owned FIEs which account for over a third of
total manufacturing output in 2009 (Figure 2). In summary, export-oriented foreign
investment has been the backbone for output growth and employment expansion in
Vietnamese manufacturing.
[Figure 1 and Figure 2 around here]
Other determinants of wage premium such as KL, RQ, and GR are statistically
significant with the expected signs. As a representation of firm’s characteristics, firm output –
a proxy for firm size – is positive and significant at the five per cent level or better in all
cases. Ceteris paribus, larger firms tend to have a widening wage premium. Moreover, the
coefficient of capital intensity (KL) is positive and significant at conventional levels. This
result is straightforward as firms with a higher proportion of capital are likely to recruit more
skilled workers. As a result, an expansion of demand for skilled workers results in a widening
of the wage premium.
In regard to worker’s characteristics, the coefficient of the gender ratio (GR) is highly
significant with an expected (positive) sign, suggesting a higher share of female workers is
likely to cause a rise in the wage premium. This is explained by the fact that a high gender
ratio is associated with a higher proportion of unskilled workers, implying that they will have
As shown in the first column in Table 4, the coefficient of skill share (SS) is significant but
carries an unexpected (negative) sign in the full model. This result is contrary to the normal
expectation that this skill ratio would contribute to the wage premium. As previously noted in
the discussion on the data compilation, this unexpected finding could be the result of
Page 15
measurement error. Wages for production workers – a proxy for unskilled workers – may
partly include those of skilled workers in the production work, leading to a magnification of
the wage for unskilled workers in the wage premium. Testing was undertaken for the possible
effects of this issue on the other explanatory variables. The results in the second specification
are significantly robust to the exclusion, given that it does not affect the significance level and
sign of coefficients on various explanatory variables.
The coefficients of the regional dummies are highly significant in the full model. The
positive coefficient of the South East Area (Sea) including Ho Chi Minh City implies that
firms operating in that region have a higher wage premium than those located in other less
urbanized regions, holding other effects constant. A similar comment also holds for those
firms located in the Red River Delta (Rrd). A plausible reason for these effects is that these
two regions have many advantages as compared to the rest of Vietnam in terms of market
competition, availability of resources, and business environment. It is important to note that
there is a notable difference between these two most urbanized regions. We conduct a test of
the effect of that difference on the wage premium, as shown in the Columns 3 and 4.
Controlling for the South East Area, the coefficient is still positive and significant while that
for the Red River Delta becomes insignificant. Clearly the evidence of the higher wage
premium for firms operating in the South East Area may be associated with the fact that the
region has been more involved with market-based disciplines than has the North.
6. Comparison results
The preceding section provides the estimation results examining the effect of trade and
investment on the wage premium. For the purpose of comparison, an estimation of the model
that relates manufacturing wages to the similar explanatory variables is also undertaken. This
analysis is based on the following model.
=β0+β1ITij+β2OTij+β3DPij+β4JVSij+ β5JVPij+ β6WFIEij