InvestmentCash Flow Sensitivities Constrained versus Unconstrained Firms
Post on: 16 Март, 2015 No Comment
![InvestmentCash Flow Sensitivities Constrained versus Unconstrained Firms InvestmentCash Flow Sensitivities Constrained versus Unconstrained Firms](/wp-content/uploads/2015/3/investmentcash-flow-sensitivities-constrained_2.jpg)
Investment-Cash Flow Sensitivities: Constrained versus Unconstrained Firms
Investment-Cash Flow Sensitivities:
Constrained versus Unconstrained Frrms
NATHALIE MOYEN*
ABSTRACT
From the existing literature, it is not clear what effect financing constraints have
on the sensitivities of firms investment to their cash flow. I propose an explanation
that reconciles the conflicting empirical evidence. I present two models: the unconstrained
model, in which firms can raise external funds, and the constrained model, in
which firms cannot do so. Using low dividends to identify financing constraints in my
generated panel of data produces results consistent with those of Fazzari, Hubbard,
and Petersen; using the constrained model produces results consistent with those of
Kaplan and Zingales.
THE LITERATURE DOCUMENTING the sensitivity offirms investment to fluctuations
in their internal funds, initiated by Fazzari, Hubbard, and Petersen (1988), is
large and growing. The sensitivity is measured by the coefficient obtained from
regressing investment on cash flow, controlling for investment opportunities
using Tobins Q. Fazzari et al. view firms as constrained when external financing
is too expensive. In that case, firms must use internal funds to finance
their investments rather than to payout dividends. Fazzari et al. identify firms
with low dividends as Most constrained and firms with high dividends as
Least constrained. As reported in Table I, Most constrained firms have investments
that are more sensitive to cash flows than Least constrained firms.
Kaplan and Zingales (1997) disagree with the interpretation of the result. Their
identification of financially constrained firms is based on the qualitative and
quantitative information contained in the firms various reports. Kaplan and
Zingales identify firms without access to more funds than needed to finance
their investment as Likely constrained and firms with access to more funds
than needed to finance their investment as Never constrained. In contrast to
Fazzari et al. Kaplan and Zingales do not consider firms that choose to pay
low dividends even though they could payout more as constrained. As Table I
indicates, the investments of Likely constrained firms are less sensitive to
Never constrained 0.702 0.009
(0.041) (0.006)
empirical evidence, I construct two models: an unconstrained model, in which
firms have perfect access to external financial markets, and a constrained
model, in which firms have no access. Section I presents the two models, and
Section II describes the calibration necessary to solve the models. Series are
simulated from the two models and pooled to represent the theoretical sample.
Using this laboratory, I investigate whether the empirical results can be
replicated. I find that they can. Section III discusses two main findings. First,
using low dividends to identify firms with financing constraints leads to Fazzari
et al.s result that low-dividend firms investment is more sensitive to cash flow
than high-dividend firms investment. Second, using the constrained model to
identify firms with financing constraints leads to Kaplan and Zingaless result
that constrained firms investment is less sensitive to cash flow than unconstrained
firms investment.
The fact that the cash flow sensitivity of firms described by the constrained
model is lower than the cash flow sensitivity of firms described by the unconstrained
model can be easily explained. In both models, cash flow is highly
correlated with investment opportunities. With more favorable opportunities,
both constrained and unconstrained firms invest more. With more favorable
opportunities, unconstrained firms also issue debt to fund additional investment.
Because the effect of debt financing on investment is not taken into
account by the regression specification, it magnifies the cash flow sensitivity of
unconstrained firms. Also, given more cash flow, unconstrained firms use debt
to increase both their investment and their dividend payment. Constrained
firms choose whether to allocate their cash flows to more investment or more
dividends. The link between investment and cash flow is therefore weaker for
constrained firms. In accord with Kaplan and Zingaless result, the cash flow
sensitivity of constrained firms is lower than that of unconstrained firms.
The fact that the cash flow sensitivity of low-dividend firms is higher than the
cash flow sensitivity of high-dividend firms can also be easily explained. Firms
Investment-Cash Flow Sensitivities 2063
from the unconstrained model invest more than firms from the constrained
model. Because unconstrained firms can adjust their debt levels through time,
they also take on more debt. Debt claimants of unconstrained firms account
for a greater portion of the firms than debt claimants of constrained firms.
Equity claimants of unconstrained firms receive smaller dividends than equity
claimants of constrained firms. Using low dividends to identify firms with financing
constraints leads to Fazzari et al.s result. Low-dividend firms are
mostly firms from the unconstrained model, which exhibit a higher cash flow
sensitivity than do firms from the constrained model.
While the empirical debate between Fazzari et al. and Kaplan and Zingales
remains unresolved, a number of theoretical papers have investigated the sensitivity
of investment to cash flow fluctuations. Using a neoclassical framework,
Gomes (2001) and Alti (2003) show that cash flow sensitivities can be generated
from an environment without any financing friction. Both Gomes and Alti
conclude that cash flow sensitivities do not necessarily indicate the presence of
financing constraints. In contrast, I investigate whether financing constraints
are sufficient to replicate the empirical evidence underlying the Fazzari et al.
and Zingales debate.
Other papers use a finance framework to examine the cash flow sensitivity
controversy. Almeida and Campello (2001) develop a one-period model in which
firms may face credit constraints. Unconstrained firms show no cash flow sensitivity,
while credit-constrained firms exhibit a positive cash flow sensitivity. The
sensitivity of credit-constrained firms increases with their available collateral.
Instead ofimposing credit constraints on investment, Povel and Raith (2001) develop
a one-period model in which investment is not observable by the market.
They find that the relation between investment and cash flow is U-shaped, and
that more information asymmetry generally increases the cash flow sensitivity.
Like Povel and Raith, Dasgupta and Sengupta (2002) assume that investment
is not observable by the market. Using a two-period model, they also find that
the relation between investment and cash flow is not monotonic. In contrast, I
focus on the dynamic behavior of firms investment policies in an environment
with complete information.
I. The Models
I compare the investment behavior of two types of firms. The first type of
firm faces no financing constraint and trades off the costs and benefits of external
financing, while the second type of firm is completely shut out of external
financial markets. Using such extreme types of firms maximizes the effect of
1 Some empirical papers provide support for Fazzari et al. while others obtain results consistent
with those of Kaplan and Zingales. The papers providing support for Fazzari et al. (1988)
include Allayannis and Mozumdar (2001), Fazzari, Hubbard, and Petersen (2000), Gilchrist and
Himmelberg (1995), Hoshi, Kashyap, and Scharfstein (1991), Oliner and Rudebusch (1992), and
Schaller (1993). See Hubbard (1998) for an extensive literature review. The papers providing support
for Kaplan and Zingales (1997) include Cleary (1999), Kadapakkam, Kumar, and Riddick
(1998), and Kaplan and Zingales (2000).
2064 The Journal ofFinance
financing constraints on the cash flow sensitivity. In other words, the cash flow
sensitivity of constrained firms is as different as possible from that of unconstrained
firms.
A. The Unconstrained Firm Model
The unconstrained firm model characterizes the investment and financing
decisions offirms that face no financing constraint. Firms trade off a tax benefit
The firm maximizes the equity value subject to fairly pricing any debt issue
by choosing its dividend, investment, and debt policies. All claimants, equity
and debt, are risk-neutral. The unconstrained equity value VU is
(1)
where the superscript u denotes unconstrained firms, r is the discount rate,
and E, is the conditional expectation at period t. For simplicity, dividends and
capital gains are assumed to be untaxed.
Equation (1) shows that the equity value is the sum of the expected discounted
stream of dividends, DU. Equation (1) also shows that equity claimants
are protected by limited liability. Equity claimants default whenever Dr+ llr
Et[Vr+l] :s o. The firm may ask its equity claimants to contribute additional
funds (Dr < 0), but equity claimants may choose to relinquish their equity claim
rather than contribute more. In the case where the equity issue is not justified
by the expected discounted future equity value (Dr+ llr Et[Vr+l] :s 0), equity
claimants exercise their option of not contributing additional funds to the firm
and trigger default instead.
The firms sources-and-uses-of-funds equation defines the dividend
where Tf is the firms tax rate, K, is the capital stock, ()t describes the firms underlying
income shock, (1 — Tf )f(Kt ; ()t) is the after-tax operating income before
depreciation, 8 is the depreciation rate, Tf8Kt is the depreciation tax shield, It is
the investment,
Bt+l is the new debt issue, Lt is the interest rate, B, is the debt
level, and (1 — Tf )LtBt is the after-tax interest payment. The depreciation rate
used for tax purposes is assumed to be equal to the true economic depreciation
rate of the capital stock.
Investment-Cash Flow Sensitivities 2065
The firms operating income before depreciation is the difference between its
Equation (6) shows that debt claimants demand an interest rate such that
the debt lent to the firm this period equals next periods expected discounted
payoff The payoff on the debt claim consists of the face value Bt+1 and the
after-tax interest payment (1 — Tt)lt+1Bt+1 if equity claimants do not default,
or the net residual value R(Kt+1;Ot+1) — XBt+1 if they default, where t, is the
debt claimants interest income tax rate, X is the deadweight default cost as a
proportion of the debt face value, and the function l(v>o) indicates no-default:
1 if V > 0,
l(v>o) == o otherwi.se.
The residual accruing to debt claimants upon default R(K; (>)is the reorganized
value of the firm. Debt claimants may then recapitalize the firm in an optimal
2 Rather than representing labor expenses as a fixed cost F, one could explicitly model the firms
labor demand decision. The firm would gain another instrument to maximize its value. The firms
operating income would become more responsive to the income shock ()t. The firm would hire more
labor in periods of high income shock and less labor in periods of low income shock. Not explicitly
modeling the labor decision makes the firms income less responsive to its shock.
2066 The Journal ofFinance
(9)
manner. In fact, R(K; () takes into account the optimal recapitalization from
that unlevered state
R(Kt; ()t) = (1 — r f) f(Kt; ()t) + 1:foKt — It + Bt+ 1 + -1-Et[V/
The firms income shock is represented by a first-order autoregressive process
with persistence p and volatility a:
In ()t+l = pIn ()t+aEt+l, (11)
where Et
i.i.d. N(O, 1). Because the persistence parameter p is not zero, the
income shock is somewhat predictable. The firm anticipates the income shock
it will face next period and chooses its investment and debt policies accordingly.
The firm cannot perfectly anticipate the income shock it will face next period.
Although the firm positions itself to limit the possibility of default next
period, default occurs when next periods income shock ()t+l turns out to be so
much lower than expected that the equity claim becomes worthless. The income
shock at which equity claimants trigger default (>U(Kt. Bt. It) is defined by Dr + llrEt[Vr+l] = o. If we substitute equations (2)-(5) into this expression,
the default point is implicitly defined by
(1- if )((>U(Kt, Bt. It)K
- F) +(1- (1- if )o)Kt — K t+ 1 + Bt+ 1
l lOt = (>U(Kt, Bt, It)] = O. (12)
not restricted to be nonnegative. The firm is allowed to sell some assets and
to retire debt. There is no need for a stock of cash in the model. The firm can
effectively manage its probability of default by buying and selling its capital
stock and by changing its financial structure.
The firm chooses how much dividend Dr to pay, how much to invest It, and how
Bt+1 at the interest rate It+1 that satisfies the bond-pricing
equation (6), in order to maximize the equity value in equation (1) subject to
equations (2)-(5). The firm makes these decisions after observing the beginningof-
aKt+1 alt+1
are defined in the Appendix.
Equation (14) states that the firm invests up to the point where the cost of one
unit of capital equals next periods expected discounted marginal contribution
to dividends. Equation (14) also shows that the firm accounts for the effects of
![InvestmentCash Flow Sensitivities Constrained versus Unconstrained Firms InvestmentCash Flow Sensitivities Constrained versus Unconstrained Firms](/wp-content/uploads/2015/3/investmentcash-flow-sensitivities-constrained_1.jpg)
its investment decision on the interest rate requested by debt claimants and on
the default probability. A higher interest rate It+1 promised to debt claimants
a[eU (K t+1, Bt+l, [t+l)]. a[eU (K t+1, Bt+l, [t+l)]),
defined in the Appendix.
The model cannot be solved analytically. The solution is approximated using
numerical methods. Once decision rules are obtained, a panel of firms is
simulated and studied.
B. The Constrained Firm Model
Without access to external markets, the model is simpler. The firms problem
is to choose its dividend D, and investment It policies to maximize the equity
value. The firm finances itself neither with debt (Bt+1 == Bt == 0) nor with equity
0). The model recognizes, however, that constrained firms are levered, as
has been documented by Fazzari et al. and by Kaplan and Zingales. It is possible
that a constrained firm has had access to external capital markets at some point
in the past, no longer has access, but is still servicing an existing debt structure.
The debt in place is assumed to be a perpetuity. The interest payment c of the
constrained firm does not vary through time, because the firm no longer has
Investment-Cash Flow Sensitivities
subject to the dividend equation
the income equation (3), and the capital accumulation equation (4).
The investment decision is characterized by
where At is the multiplier disallowing equity issues. Equation (18) states that
r == 0.95, and the depreciation rate [)
to 0.1. The tax rates are calibrated to reflect the U.S. corporate and personal tax
rates of 40% and 20%: if == 0.4 and it == 0.2. The default cost is set toX == 0.1, as
a compromise between Fischer, Heinkel, and Zechner (1989) and Kane, Marcus,
and McDonald (1984), who calibrate this cost to 5% and 15% of the debt face
value.
Moyen (1999) estimates the sensitivity parameter (1, the persistence p, and
the volatility a from annual COMPUSTAT data using the firms income equation
(3) and the autoregressive income shock process of equation (11). Accordingly,
the sensitivity of the firms income-to-capital stock variations is set to
(1 == 0.45, the persistence to p == 0.6, and the volatility to a == 0.2.
The long-term coupon is set to C == 0.15 to maximize the ex ante constrained
firm value Vo+Lo, where the perpetual debt value L, is defined in the next
2070 The Journal ofFinance
section. The coupon is expressed in relation to the numeraire, which is the
value ofa unit ofincomef(Kt. Bt ). For example, ifincome were scaled to $f(Kt. Bt )
millions, the coupon per period to be paid by the firm would be $150,000.
The fixed cost representing labor and other expenses F is calibrated to obtain
a reasonable average debt-to-capital stock ratio of 0.6. In the constrained firm
model, this debt-to-capital stock ratio is obtained with a fixed cost of 0.45.
In the unconstrained firm model, this debt-to-capital stock ratio is obtained
with a higher fixed cost of 1.35.3 A higher fixed cost simply reduces the debt
level that can be serviced by the firm. As is discussed below, constrained firms
turn out to be smaller on average than unconstrained firms. When I calibrate
the fixed labor cost to obtain a reasonable debt-to-capital stock ratio, smaller
constrained firms appropriately face a smaller cost than larger unconstrained
firms.
Given these parameter values, the two models are solved numerically as
described in the Appendix. The resulting series It, t,.Bt+1. It+1, and Vt are simulated
from random outcomes of the income shock Et. A sample of 1,000 unconstrained
firms and 1,000 constrained firms is generated, where each series for
which no default v, > 0 occurs for at least 10 consecutive periods defines a firm.
I simulate an equal number of constrained and unconstrained firms because
it is difficult to know how many firms in the data currently have easy access
to external markets. The robustness of the results to different proportions of
these two types of firms is discussed in the next section.
Unconstrained firms sometimes default. For example, 0.69% of the unconstrained
firms default in periods 11-20. Equity claimants sometimes choose a
debt level that is too burdensome to service when next periods income shock
turns out to be much lower than expected. Constrained firms do not default.
The perpetual coupon chosen ex ante to maximize the firm value is not high
enough to generate zero dividends forever.
III. Results
A. Investment-Cash Flow Sensitivities
Table II shows that the cash flow sensitivity of firms identified as experiencing
financing constraints may be higher or lower than that of firms identified
as experiencing no constraint, depending on the identification criterion used.
The simulated sample of2,000 firms over 10 periods is divided into two groups,
firms with financing constraints and firms without constraint, on the basis of
five criteria. Firms are alternatively identified as experiencing financing constraints
if they have low dividends, if they have low cash flows, if they are
indeed constrained as described by the constrained firm model, if they are described
by the constrained firm model and exhaust their internal funds when
investing, or if they have low Clearys (1999) index values.
3 The results are robust to different labor cost F values. A sensitivity analysis is available upon
request.
Investment-Cash Flow Sensitivities 2071
Table II
Regression Results from Simulated Series
The measure K denotes the capital stock, CF cash flow,QTobins average q, D+ dividend, Athe multiplier
disallowing equity issues in the constrained firm model, and ZFC the financial constraints
index developed by Cleary (1999). Standard errors appear in parentheses. The portions of firm-year
observations identified as experiencing financing constraint, appear in brackets. The difference in
cash flow sensitivities between firms with financing constraints and firms with no constraint is
statistically significant at the 5% level for all regressions.
Firms identified by dividends:
Financing constraints-firms with low If-
No constraint-firms with high If-
Firms identified by cash flows:
Financing constraints-firms with low fJNo
constraint-firms with high fJFirms
identified by models:
Financing constraints-firms from the constrained model
No constraint-firms from the unconstrained model