Federal Reserve Bank San Francisco
Post on: 8 Апрель, 2016 No Comment
Fed Tapering News and Emerging Markets
Fed Tapering News and Emerging Markets
Fernanda Nechio
In 2013, the Federal Reserve publicly described conditions for scaling back and ultimately ending its highly accommodative monetary policy. Some emerging market countries subsequently experienced sharp reversals of capital inflows, resulting in sizable currency depreciation. But others did not. Variations in financial market reactions from one country to another appear to have been related to differences in economic conditions, which partly reflected a country’s policies before the Fed’s tapering comments.
In the wake of the global financial crisis and recession of 2007–09, the Federal Reserve carried out a series of large-scale purchases of government and asset-backed securities to lower longer-term interest rates and provide additional stimulus to the economy. Following then-Chairman Ben Bernanke’s May 22, 2013, congressional testimony about the possibility that the Federal Reserve would begin scaling back these purchases—a reduction widely known as tapering—some financial market participants revised their beliefs about when the central bank would begin normalizing its highly accommodative monetary policy. Market participants moved forward the dates they expected the Fed to start reducing its large-scale asset purchases as well as the dates when they expected it to start raising the federal funds rate, its short-term policy interest rate (Bauer and Rudebusch 2013).
These changes in policy expectations led to reductions in market participants’ tolerance for risk and in particular to a downward reassessment of the probable returns from investing in emerging market economies. Following the global financial crisis, advanced economies put in place exceptionally easy monetary policy. During this period, many emerging market economies had received large waves of capital inflows. By contrast, after Chairman Bernanke’s testimony, many emerging market economies in Asia and Latin America experienced sharp capital flow reversals.
However, the distribution of these capital movements was not uniform. Patterns of capital outflows appeared to be related to a country’s macroeconomic fundamentals. Those in turn reflected to some degree the policies a country pursued during the years that followed the global financial crisis. This Economic Letter assesses how recent emerging market capital movements are related to a country’s economic situation. In particular, countries with larger external and internal imbalances during the low interest rate period faced larger currency depreciations when interest rate expectations for advanced economies tightened.
Figure 1
Emerging market bond and equity fund flows
Source: Powell (2013a).
Capital flow reversals following tapering news
Capital inflows to emerging economies peaked in January 2013, slowed in the first half of 2013, and sharply reversed in the months immediately following Chairman Bernanke’s May comments. Figure 1 shows capital flows to emerging Asia and Latin America (from Powell 2013a). Foreign investments started to decline before May, perhaps in response to the improvements in U.S. economic fundamentals that motivated consideration of asset purchase tapering in the first place. Nonetheless, large capital outflows from emerging Asia and Latin America appear to have coincided with the May testimony.
These large capital outflows indicate that investors interpreted Chairman Bernanke’s statements as implying an impending reduction in monetary accommodation. A number of Fed policymakers subsequently tried to reassure investors that actual removal of monetary policy accommodation was still far off (for example, Dudley 2013, Williams 2013, and Powell 2013b). In addition, they stressed that the liftoff date for moving the federal funds rate above its lower bound near zero was not linked to the pace of tapering of asset purchases. Tapering would merely slow the rate at which the Fed would be adding assets to its portfolio. Despite these qualifications, the taper scare apparently prompted an overall reduction in investment in riskier assets, including assets from emerging economies.
Role of weak fundamentals in the severity of capital flow reversals
Recent research in international finance has found that sharp retrenchments of capital flows, known as sudden stops, depend not only on external factors, such as changes in expectations for advanced economy monetary policies, but also on internal domestic macroeconomic fundamentals (for example, see Forbes and Warnock 2012, and Edwards 2007). In particular, sudden stops in capital flows can reflect disappointments in a country’s domestic economic growth or concerns about its growing internal and external imbalances.
Fiscal and current account balances are commonly used measures to assess respectively a country’s internal and external balances. The fiscal balance is the difference between government revenues and expenditures. A negative fiscal balance, i.e. a fiscal deficit, is a measure of internal imbalance because it implies an increase in public borrowing. The current account balance includes a country’s trade balance, that is, its exports minus imports, plus international cash transfers, and earnings on foreign investments minus payments to foreign investors. A country that runs a current account deficit consumes and invests more than it produces, and accumulates a negative net foreign asset position with other countries.
Combinations of disappointing output growth and increases in external and internal imbalances may jeopardize the perception of global investors that a country will be able to honor its outstanding liabilities. This can generate a downward reassessment of expected investment returns in that country and fuel a retrenchment of capital inflows.
The onset of a sudden stop may itself cause difficulties that ratify investor expectations of lower returns. Thus, sudden stops may be costly for emerging market countries. They create pressure for countries to depreciate their currencies, which can boost inflation. Fighting inflation may require tighter monetary policy, which could further reduce growth. In addition, currency depreciations leave countries less able to service debts denominated in foreign currencies.
Figure 2
Exchange rate depreciation, May to December 2013
Source: Bloomberg
The episode of capital flow retrenchment noted earlier seems to confirm the predictions in the international finance literature about the effects of sudden stops on capital inflows and emerging market currencies. Figure 2 compares the magnitude of currency depreciation among a sample of emerging market countries from May to December 2013, including Brazil, India, Indonesia, Turkey, South Africa, South Korea, Malaysia, Philippines, Singapore, Thailand, Chile, Mexico, Colombia, and Peru. The first five have been referred to in the financial press as the “fragile five,” because they are seen as more dependent on foreign capital flows and as exhibiting higher risk of currency depreciation against the dollar (see Morgan Stanley 2013).