Does a Central Clearing Counterparty Reduce Counterparty Risk

Post on: 11 Июнь, 2015 No Comment

Does a Central Clearing Counterparty Reduce Counterparty Risk

Abstract

JEL codes

1. Introduction

A key element of the new regulatory approach to financial stability is the central clearing of derivatives. A central clearing counterparty (CCP) stands between over-the-counter (OTC) derivatives counterparties, insulating them from each other’s default. Effective clearing mitigates systemic risk by lowering the likelihood that defaults propagate from counterparty to counterparty. Clearing could also reduce the degree to which the solvency problems of a market participant are suddenly compounded by a flight of its OTC derivative counterparties, such as when the solvency of Bear Stearns and Lehman Brothers was in question.1 Finally, central clearing reduces the risk of disruptions to financial markets through fire sales of derivatives positions or of collateral held against derivatives positions.

The Dodd-Frank Act of the United States Congress, passed in July 2010, stipulates that all sufficiently standard derivatives traded by major market participants must be cleared in regulated CCPs. The European Commission (2010) has taken similar steps.

Our objective is to model whether the central clearing of a particular class of derivatives increases or reduces counterparty exposures. For plausible cases, adding a new CCP dedicated to a class of derivatives such as credit default swaps (CDS) reduces netting efficiency, increases collateral demands, and leads to higher average exposure to counterparty default. We further show that counterparty credit risk in the OTC derivatives market is exacerbated by a multiplicity of CCPs. Using recent data on the OTC derivatives positions of U.S. banks, we provide illustrative numerical examples of the adverse counterparty-risk impact of splitting clearing across CCPs. We also prove that counterparty risk is always reduced by merging the clearing activities of multiple CCPs into a single CCP. For CDS alone, approved CCPs include two based in the United States and several based in Europe. A number of additional CDS clearing houses have been proposed for the United States, Europe, and Asia.2 Attempts to obtain the effective benefits of concentrating clearing into fewer CCPs through cross-CCP “interoperability” agreements appear to be stalled by both technical and strategic impediments.

While the central clearing of derivatives can in principle offer substantial reductions in counterparty risk, we provide a foundation for concerns that these benefits may be lost through a fragmentation of clearing services.

Our results are based on a simple model, but clarify an important tradeoff between two types of netting opportunities: bilateral netting between pairs of counterparties across different underlying assets, versus multilateral netting among many clearing participants across a single class of derivatives, such as credit default swaps (CDS). The introduction of a CCP for a particular class such as standard credit derivatives is effective only if the opportunity for multilateral netting in that class dominates the resulting loss in bilateral netting opportunities across all uncleared derivatives, such as uncleared CDS and uncleared OTC derivatives of equities, interest rates, commodities, and foreign exchange, among others.

The intuition of our results is simple. Suppose that Dealer A is exposed to Dealer B by $100 million on CDS, while at the same time Dealer B is exposed to Dealer A by $150 million on interest-rate swaps. The bilateral exposure is the net, $50 million. The introduction of central clearing dedicated to CDS eliminates the bilateral netting benefits and increases the exposure between these two dealers, before collateral, from $50 million to $150 million. In addition to any collateral posted by Dealer A to the CCP for CDS, Dealer A would need to post a significant amount of additional collateral to Dealer B. Collateral is a scarce resource, especially in a credit crisis.

The introduction of a CCP for CDS can nevertheless be effective when there are extensive opportunities for multilateral netting. For example, if Dealer A is exposed by $100 million to Dealer B through a CDS, while Dealer B is exposed to Dealer C for $100 million on the same CDS, and Dealer C is simultaneously exposed to Dealer A for the same amount on the same CDS, then a CCP eliminates this unnecessary circle of exposures. The introduction of a CCP therefore involves an important tradeoff between bilateral netting without the CCP and multilateral netting through the CCP.

Naturally, our results show that introducing a CCP for a particular set of derivatives reduces average counterparty exposures if and only if the number of clearing participants is sufficiently large relative to the exposure on derivatives that continue to be bilaterally netted. For example, our model suggests that clearing CDS through a dedicated CCP improves netting efficiency for twelve similarly sized dealers if and only if the fraction of a typical dealer’s total expected exposure attributable to cleared CDS is at least 66% of the total expected exposure of remaining bilaterally netted classes of derivatives. It is far from obvious that clearable exposures in the CDS market are nearly this large.

Our results show that a single central clearing counterparty that clears both credit derivatives and interest-rate swaps is likely to offer significant reductions in expected counterparty exposures, even for a relatively small number of clearing participants. For example, in a simple illustrative calculation based on data provided by U.S. banks, we show that once 75% of interest-rate swaps are cleared, the incremental reduction in before-collateral average expected counterparty exposures obtained by clearing 75% of credit derivatives in a separate CCP is negligible, because of the loss of bilateral netting opportunities. In the same setting, however, clearing these credit derivatives in the same CCP used for interest-rate swaps reduces average expected exposures by about 7%, despite the loss of bilateral netting opportunities. Relative to the case of fully bilateral netting (no clearing), substantial benefits can be obtained by the joint clearing of the four major classes of derivatives monitored by the Office of the Comptroller of the Currency. Our rough estimates suggest that the joint clearing of 75% of interest-rate swaps and credit derivatives, along with 40% of other derivatives classes, results in a 37% reduction in pre-collateral expected counterparty exposures, relative to a market without CCPs.

2. Netting Efficiency in an OTC Market

We consider N market participants whose over-the-counter derivative exposures to each other are of concern. These entities may have the opportunity to novate some OTC derivative positions to a central clearing counterparty (CCP). For example, if entities i and j have a CDS position by which i buys protection from j. then both i and j can novate to a CCP, who is then the seller of protection to i and the buyer of protection from j. Novation to a CCP is sometimes called “clearing,” although the term “clearing” is often used in other contexts.3

We allow for K classes of derivatives. These classes could be defined by the underlying asset classes, such as credit, interest rates, foreign exchange, commodities, and equities. One can also construct derivatives classes by grouping more than one underlying asset type, or by separating the derivatives in a given asset into the subset of derivatives that are sufficiently standard to be cleared and the complementary set of derivatives that are too customized or thinly traded to justify clearing.

We take the perspective of a regulator or industry coordinator that is considering the design of the market clearing architecture from the viewpoint of exposures of market participants to each other on a typical day in the future, well after the architecture has been chosen and market participants have determined their approaches to clearing.

For entities i and j. let X i j k be the amount that j will owe i in all positions in some derivatives class k. before considering the benefits of netting across asset classes, collateral, and default recovery.4 We call max(X i j k ,0) the exposure of i to j in derivative class k. This exposure is the amount entity i risks losing upon the default of entity j. Similarly, the exposure of entity j to i is max( − X i j k ,0) because, by definition, (1)

Before setting up a CCP, X i j k is uncertain in part because the derivatives positions between i and j that will exist on this typical future day, possibly years in the future, are yet to be determined. The volatilities and correlations of prices on that future date are also uncertain at the point of market design. The exposure also reflects uncertainty regarding the degree of netting that is achieved in the master swap agreements, due in part to uncertain changes in market prices before this future date. In addition, the uncertainty in X i j k includes the risks associated with marks to market that will occur between the times at which additional collateral can be requested and received, respectively.

We emphasize that the uncertainty regarding X i j k that matters from the viewpoint of market design some months or years before the exposure date cannot be based on conditioning information that becomes available just before this future date. In particular, a market designer cannot know in advance the notional sizes of derivatives positions that will be in place at a future time. Position uncertainty, both size and direction, is to be incorporated into the probability distribution of the future exposures. This distinction is also important for other CCP design problems, such as the sizing of the CCP’s capital, initial margin requirements, and default guarantee fund, which are chosen well in advance, with the objective of being sufficient for default management across a wide variety of portfolios that could be submitted for clearing and across a wide variety of market price volatilities and correlations.

For now, we suppose that all (X i j k ) are of the same variance and are independent across asset classes and pairs of entities, excluding the obvious case represented by (1). We later relax all of these assumptions. For simplicity, we assume symmetry in the distributions of exposures across all pairs of entities. This implies in particular that E (X i j k ) = 0. We will also relax the symmetry assumption. With N entities and K asset classes, there are K ×N ×(N − 1)/2 exposure distributions to be specified. Symmetry allows a dramatic reduction in the dimension of the problem.

A reasonable measure of the netting efficiency offered by a market structure is the total expected counterparty exposures of a typical entity, say entity i. to the default of the other (N − 1) entities, before collateral is considered. Under bilateral netting, the exposure of i to any one of its counterparties, say j. is netted across all K derivative classes, but exposures to different counterparties cannot be netted. Before introducing a CCP, therefore, the total netting efficiency is (2) where we have used symmetry by fixing attention on a particular entity i. Assuming normality of X i j k and symmetry across all N − 1 counterparties, we have (3) where σ is the standard deviation of X i j k.

For given collateralization standards, the risk of loss caused by a counterparty default is typically increasing in average expected exposure. (Under normality and symmetry, essentially any reasonable risk measure is increasing in expected exposure.) Risk of loss from counterparty default is a first-order consideration for systemic risk analysis.

Going beyond counterparty default risk, as expected exposures go up, the expected amount of collateral that must be supplied goes up. Collateral use is expensive. In an OTC market without a CCP, whatever collateral is supplied by one counterparty is received by another, so the net use of collateral is always zero. The need to supply collateral is nevertheless onerous, for several reasons. First, some individual counterparties on a given day will supply more collateral to others than others supplied to them. The net drain on the assets that could be supplied as collateral is costly, because of the lost opportunity to use that collateral for secured borrowing, as a cash management buffer, or for securities lending as a rent-earning business. Second, there is a question of the timing of collateral settlement. One must often supply collateral to a particular counterparty on a given day before collateral is received from another counterparty. If this were not the case, for instance, there would be no specials in treasury repo markets. This sort of frictional demand for collateral, analogous to the demand for money that arises from a limited velocity of circulation of money, is considered by Duffie, Gârleanu, and Pedersen (2002). So long as the average cost of supplying collateral to others is larger, on average, than the average benefit of receiving collateral from others, a market with poorer netting efficiency is also a market with higher net cost of collateral use. For a simple illustration, if the amount of collateral to be supplied is on average some multiple U of exposure, and if the average benefit b per unit of collateral value received is less than the average cost c per unit of collateral value supplied, then the average net expected cost to an entity of collateral usage arising from counterparty exposure is (cb )U ϕ N ,K . where ϕ N ,K is the average total expected exposure measure defined above. Under market stress, collateral demand from derivative counterparties could exacerbate the liquidity problem of an already weakened dealer bank, as explained by Duffie (2010).

Although average expected exposure, after netting and before collateral, is a reasonable measure of a market’s netting efficiency and is closely related to systemic risk, this measure misses some important aspects of systemic risk. Most importantly, this measure does not consider the joint determination of defaults across entities. In particular, as opposed to the joint solvency analysis of Eisenberg and Noe (2001). our netting efficiency measure does not consider the implications of jointly determined defaults in a network of entities. For example, the likelihood that entity i cannot cover its payments to j plays a causal role in determining the likelihood that entity j cannot cover its payments to entity m. and so on. Adding a CCP could in principle increase or decrease the potential for jointly determined defaults, depending on the capitalization of the CCP and of the clearing entities, and on the collateralization standards of bilateral netting and central clearing. In addition to the capital that it holds, a CCP is typically backed by member guarantees. (See the appendix of Duffie, Li, and Lubke 2010 .) An analysis of the implications of a CCP for the joint solvency of its members is beyond the scope of our research.

In addition to the benefits of a CCP from the viewpoint of netting and of insulating counterparties from each other’s default, a well-run central clearing counterparty can also offer improved and more harmonized trade and collateral settlement procedures than those that apply to uncleared derivatives, as suggested by the Bank for International Settlements (2007).

The assumption of normality clearly does not apply well to the changes in market value of many types of individual derivatives positions, such as individual CDS contracts, which have heavily skewed and fat-tailed market values due to jump-to-default risk. Bearing in mind that the modeled distribution of the exposures includes uncertainty regarding position sizes and directions, aggregating within the class of standard CDS could result in a net exposure of one entity to another that is substantially less skewed and less fat-tailed, given the diversification across underlying names and the effect of aggregating across long and short positions. For example, two dealers running large and active matched-book CDS intermediation businesses could have almost no skew in the distributions of their exposures to each other. That said, one cannot claim enough diversification from position diversification to justify normality based on a central-limit-theorem argument.

3. Netting Efficiency with a CCP

We consider the implications of a CCP for one class of derivatives, say class K. Taking the previously described setting, suppose that all positions in class K are novated to the same CCP. The expected exposure of entity i to this CCP is then (4) In practice, the exposure of a clearing participant to a CCP has two components. The first part is the direct exposure to the failure of the CCP, as to any other counterparty. We have explicitly modeled this source of exposure. The second part of the exposure to the CCP is indirect, in the form of new contributions by the entity to the CCP guarantee fund that are payable in the event that one or more other members of the CCP fail. The latter exposure depends in part on the CCP rules for collateral, guarantee funds, and default management.5 We have not modeled these indirect exposures. Our measure of netting efficiency is thus likely to be somewhat biased in favor of clearing.

The expected exposure of entity i to the other N − 1 entities for the remaining K − 1 classes of derivatives is ϕ N ,K − 1. Thus, with a CCP for one class of derivatives, the average expected exposure is (5) Introducing a CCP for this single class of derivatives therefore improves netting efficiency if and only if γ N + ϕ N ,K − 1 < ϕ N ,K . which applies if and only if (6) Because a CCP normally collects initial margin from its members, but does not provide initial margins to them, a CCP usually does not post as much collateral to its counterparties as it receives from them. Thus, the comparison (6) overstates the benefits of a CCP from the viewpoint of collateral efficiency.

Based on (6), if there are K = 2 symmetric classes of uncleared derivatives, then central clearing of one of the classes improves netting efficiency if and only if there are at least seven entities clearing. If there are four symmetric classes of derivatives, then central clearing of one of the classes improves efficiency if and only if there are at least fifteen entities clearing. A CCP is always preferred, in terms of netting efficiency, if it handles all classes of derivatives (which is, in effect, the case of K = 1).

In Appendix A. we allow for correlations across derivatives classes, and show that the benefit of introducing central clearing increases if there is positive cross-class exposure correlation. We also point out that counterparties have an incentive to create exposures with each other that are negatively correlated across asset classes, in order to hedge their counterparty risks.

It could be argued that the exposure of an entity to a CCP is likely to be of less concern than its exposure to another entity, because a CCP is likely to be well regulated, bearing in mind the systemic risk posed by the potential failure of a CCP. We do not model this “benefit” of a CCP; our average expected exposure measure weights all counterparty exposures equally. Arguing the other way, the centrality of a CCP implies that its failure risk could be more toxic than that of other market participants.6 Likewise, we do not consider this effect.7

Our measure of netting efficiency is based on the total of the expected exposures of an entity to its counterparties. This measure does not consider concentration risk. Even putting aside the systemic risk of a CCP caused by its centrality, a CCP tends to represent a concentration of exposure to its counterparties. In our simple setting, this is true whenever the number of entities clearing one of the classes of derivatives is greater than the number of derivatives classes; that is, N > K. Specifically, the expected exposure of an entity to its CCP, as a multiple of that entity’s expected exposure to each of its other counterparties, is . For instance, if there are N = 10 entities and K = 5 classes of equally risky derivatives, then after novation of positions in one class to a CCP, the expected exposure of an entity to the CCP is 50% more than its exposure to any other counterparty.8

Does a Central Clearing Counterparty Reduce Counterparty Risk

3.1. Derivatives classes with different degrees of risk

We now generalize by considering the netting efficiency allowed by the central clearing of a class of derivatives that could have particularly large exposures relative to other classes of derivatives. That is, we now allow the expected exposure E [max(X i j k ,0)] of class k to be different from that of another class. Our other assumptions are maintained. A class could include derivatives with more than one underlying asset type. For example, we could group together all CDS and all interest-rate swaps into a single class for clearing purposes.

Suppose that derivatives in class K are under consideration for clearing. The ratio of an entity’s expected exposure with a given counterparty in this asset class to the total expected exposure with the same counterparty in all other classes combined is (7) For example, if all classes have equal expected exposures, then R =, using the fact that expected exposures are proportional to standard deviations. If class-K exposures are twice as big (in terms of expected exposure) as each of the other K − 1 classes, then . A calculation analogous to that shown previously for the symmetric case leads to the following result.

Proposition 1. The introduction of a CCP for a particular class of derivatives leads to a reduction in average expected counterparty exposures if and only if (8) where R is the ratio of the pre-CCP expected entity-to-entity exposures of the class in question to the expected entity-to-entity exposures of all other classes combined.

For example, we can take the case of N = 12 entities, approximately the number of entities that partnered with ICE Trust in its CCP for clearing credit default swaps.9 Under our assumptions, with N = 12, clearing the derivatives in a particular class through a CCP improves netting efficiency if and only if the fraction R of an entity’s expected exposure attributable to this class is at least 66% of the total expected exposure of all remaining bilaterally netted classes derivatives. With N = 26, the cutoff level drops to R = 41.7%. Although the CDS market poses a large amount of exposure risk, with a total notional market size of roughly $25 trillion, it would be difficult to make the case that it represents as much as 41.7% of dealers’ expected exposures in all other “uncleared” derivatives classes combined.

The Bank for International Settlements (BIS) provides data on OTC derivatives exposures of dealers in several major asset classes. The latest available data, for June 2010, are shown in Table 1. Although these data show merely gross current credit exposures, and therefore do not incorporate the add-on exposure uncertainty associated with uncertain future position sizes and risky marks to market, they do give a rough indication of the relative amount of exposure in each of the major underlying asset classes, before netting across classes and before collateral. The effect of bilateral netting across classes reduced the total gross exposures shown in Table 1 from $24.7 trillion to $3.6 trillion.10

Table 1

Gross credit exposures in OTC derivative markets as of June 2010

In light of Proposition 1, it would be hard to base a case for the netting benefits of a central clearing counterparty dedicated to credit default swaps on the magnitudes of OTC derivatives credit exposures shown in Table 1. Credit derivatives account for less than 7% of the total gross exposures. If one assumes that total counterparty expected exposures of a given dealer are proportional, class by class, to the gross credit exposures shown in Table 1. and that X i j k are independent across k. the implied ratio R of expected exposures on credit derivatives to expected exposures on the total of other classes is less than11 10%. This would in turn imply, from Proposition 1, that a central clearing counterparty dedicated to CDS reduces average expected counterparty exposures if there are more than 460 entities clearing together. After adding to gross exposures the add-on effect of highly volatile CDS marks to market (relative to other asset classes), the threshold number of entities necessary to justify a central clearing counterparty dedicated to CDS is likely to be lower.

Exposures on credit derivatives among dealers have been reduced significantly since June 2008 due to CDS compression trades.12 According to DTCC DerivServ data, dealer CDS positions continued to shrink throughout 2008–2010. The total size of the CDS market in terms of notional positions in June 2010 was less than half of mid-2008 levels.13

The data in Table 1 suggest that there is a much stronger case for the joint clearing of CDS and interest-rate swaps, which together accounted for about 80% of the total gross exposures. Indeed, interest-rate swaps on their own represent large enough exposures to justify a dedicated central clearing counterparty, and a significant fraction of interest-rate swaps are already cleared through CCPs.14

Ironically, our model suggests that it is easier to justify the netting benefits of a central clearing counterparty dedicated to a particular class of derivatives after a different CCP has already been set up for a different class of derivatives. In this sense, “one mistake justifies another.” For example, the threshold size of the CDS market that justifies the netting benefits of a CDS-dedicated CCP is lowered once a significant fraction of interest-rate swaps are cleared.

One could argue that CDS exposure is rather special, because of jump-to-default risk and because default risk tends to be correlated with systemic risk. Given the typical practice of daily re-collateralization, the revaluation of CDS positions caused by any defaults on a given day would need to be extremely large in order to build a strong case for separate CDS clearing on the implications of jump-to-default risk. Our results show that jump-to-default risk is better reduced through bilateral netting or joint clearing with interest-rate swaps, unless the jump-to-default risk is large relative to that of all other OTC derivatives exposures. A large fraction, about one-third, of the gross credit exposures shown in Table 1 are multi-name CDS products, mainly in the form of index contracts such as CDX and iTraxx, which represent equal-weighted CDS positions in over one hundred corporate borrowers. These products have relatively small jump-to-default risk compared with single-name CDS.

The benefit of multilateral netting among a large set of entities is reduced by a concentration of exposures among a small subset of the entities. For example, among U.S. banks, the latest data available through the Office of the Comptroller of the Currency as of this writing show that the five largest derivative dealers—JPMorgan Chase, Bank of America, Goldman Sachs, Morgan Stanley, and Citigroup—account for about 95% of total notional credit derivatives positions held by all U.S. banks. The effective number of U.S. CDS market participants for purposes of our analysis may not be much more than five. The proposal for derivatives clearing becomes relatively more attractive if a single CCP handles clearing for all standard CDS positions of large global dealers, including those in Europe and the United States, and much more attractive if credit derivatives are cleared together with interest-rate swaps in the same central clearing counterparty.

3.2 An example of exposure reduction

We now provide a simple illustrative example of exposure reduction under various clearing scenarios for the six largest U.S. derivatives dealers. Table 2 shows the notional amounts of OTC derivatives contracts reported to the Office of the Comptroller of the Currency.15 Because we do not have similar data for non-U.S. banks, we assume there are six other derivatives dealers with the same total notional amounts of derivatives by class, giving a total of N = 12 major dealers globally.


Categories
Cash  
Tags
Here your chance to leave a comment!