An Assessment of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac s Contribution to the Financial Crisis of 2008
Post on: 11 Май, 2015 No Comment
Jason Thomas, CFA
Department of Finance
George Washington University
December 14, 2009
Abstract
Some observers contend that the housing government-sponsored enterprises (GSEs), Fannie Mae
and Freddie Mac, were responsible for the financial crisis due to their financial support for the
subprime mortgage market. This paper reviews the available evidence and concludes that while
Fannie and Freddie played a role in the propagation of the financial crisis, they were hardly the
mortgages purchased and securitized by the GSEs. The GSEs responded by purchasing the AAA
pieces of subprime asset-backed securities (ABS) and later purchased large quantities of Alt-A
loans. However, the GSEs’ mortgage loan portfolios performed much better than the national
average and the losses that nearly brought down the financial system were on instruments wholly
unrelated to the GSEs. Moreover, critics of the GSEs focused on interest rate risk while the
problems that ultimately led to their insolvency related to market and credit risk.
1. Introduction
On September 7, 2008, the Federal Housing Finance Agency (FHFA), in conjunction
with the Treasury Department and the Federal Reserve Board of Governors, placed Fannie Mae
and Freddie Mac, the shareholder-owned housing government sponsored enterprises (GSEs) into
conservatorship. This legal status is similar to bankruptcy: top management was removed, the
remaining shareholders’ equity was nearly wiped out, and the government assumed day-to-day
operation of both enterprises. The government took this step because the losses at the GSEs had
accelerated in recent months and analyses performed by regulators suggested that they had
insufficient capital to withstand expected future losses.1
As part of the conservatorship, the Treasury Department pledged to invest up to $200
billion in both GSEs as necessary to ensure they maintained a positive net worth.2 This amount
was later increased to $400 billion on February 18, 2009.3 As of the 3rd quarter of 2009, Fannie
Mae had formally requested $55.6 billion and Freddie Mac had requested $50.7 billion in capital
injections, requiring taxpayers to provide $106.3 billion in financing just so the GSEs could
maintain a positive net worth (FHFA, 2009). Even with no additional losses, if the GSEs were
recapitalized so as to maintain core capital at pre-conservatorship levels, it is likely that
taxpayers would have to invest an additional $121 billion, although no policy decision on that
front has yet been made (FHFA Capital, 2009).
Given the magnitude of the losses at the GSEs and the fact that the financial crisis
seemed to have originated in the residential housing finance market, some commentators have
suggested that the GSEs bear most of the responsibility for the financial crisis. This contention
www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/press/other/20080907a.htm, and
www.treasury.gov/press/releases/hp1129.htm.
2 See Treasury Senior Preferred Stock Purchase plan:
www.treas.gov/press/releases/reports/pspa_factsheet_090708%20hp1128.pdf.
www.ustreas.gov/press/releases/tg33.htm.
Page 3
is often augmented by a “we told you so” refrain from those who argued in the earlier part of the
decade that Fannie and Freddie posed a “systemic risk” to the financial system. That Fannie and
Freddie required an expensive taxpayer-financed rescue just years after they were identified as a
systemic risk provides an ephemeral confirmation for this line of reasoning.
However, closer analysis reveals this narrative to be quite unsatisfying. It is generally
agreed that the crisis began in the summer of 2007 in short-term collateralized lending markets,
not in the so-called “Agency” debt market. Moreover, it was the default rates on mortgages sold
into non-Agency pools that first caught investors’ attention and led to the failure of two Bear
Stearns-sponsored hedge funds in July 2007. If the GSEs were responsible for the financial
crisis, it seems odd, to say the least, that the onset of the liquidity crisis would occur in funding
markets they did not access and was precipitated by defaults on mortgages they did not purchase.
This paper relies on data from the Federal Reserve, the Government Accountability
Office (GAO), and Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac’s annual reports and monthly volume
summaries to assess the extent to which the data support or refute critics’ narrative about the
GSEs’ contribution to the financial crisis.
2. The GSE Policy Debate
Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac are Congressionally-chartered to provide liquidity to the
secondary mortgage market by buying mortgages from originators. They are unique in that they
are considered “Federal Government Agencies” even though they are owned by shareholders and
their debt is not explicitly guaranteed by the United States Treasury. The GSEs raise funds from
investors to purchase mortgages by issuing mortgage-backed securities (MBS) or what is
referred to as “Agency debt.” The acquired mortgages are then deposited in an off-balance sheet
special purpose vehicle (SPV) or sometimes held as whole loans on balance sheet. Although the
Page 4
GSEs retain the credit risk on the mortgage however its purchase is financed, the GSEs only
record the value of the mortgage on balance sheet when it is debt-financed. The GSEs also have
to record the value of the mortgage on balance sheet in those cases where they later issue debt to
repurchase the MBS originally issued to investors. The on-balance sheet portion of the GSEs’
mortgage holdings is called the “retained portfolio” and became the central issue in the policy
debate.
In April 2005, Federal Reserve Chairman Alan Greenspan testified before the Senate
Banking Committee to urge lawmakers to pass legislation to reform the regulation of Fannie Mae
and Freddie Mac. Greenspan put the challenge to lawmakers in stark terms: “To fend off
possible future systemic difficulties, which we assess as likely if GSE expansion continues
unabated, preventive actions are required sooner rather than later” (emphasis added). The
systemic crisis Greenspan suggested the Federal Reserve viewed as “likely” absent “preventative
actions” was thought to arise from the risks presented by the GSEs’ issuance of implicitly-
guaranteed debt to accumulate the retained portfolios. In addition to Greenspan’s testimony, the
Federal Reserve released two studies in 2005 that argued that much the market value of the
GSEs’ shareholders’ equity came from the implicit guarantee on the Agency debt (Passmore,
2005) and that the GSE portfolio purchases had a negligible impact on mortgage rates (Lehnert,
Passmore, & Sherlund, 2005). Greenspan recommended that Congress should enact a law to (1)
create a new regulator for Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac and (2) restrict the ability of the GSEs to
hold retained portfolios.
From 1998 to 2002, the combined mortgage portfolios of the GSEs more than doubled in
size, from $670 billion to $1.36 trillion (Monthly Funding Summaries). During this four year
period, retained portfolio purchases accounted for over 51% of the growth in the GSEs’ total
book of business. This was a 13 point increase from the end of 1997, when the portfolio
accounted for only 38% of total mortgage holdings. The GSEs increasingly relied on debt
instead of MBS to fund mortgages for two reasons: (1) it was more profitable to earn the spread
on mortgage coupons over Agency debt interest payments than it was to pass-through those
coupons (minus guarantee fees) to the holders of MBS; and (2) the fiscal position of the federal
government changed so dramatically at the end of 1990s that there was substantial foreign
investor demand for an alternative to Treasury securities. From 1995-1999, net foreign
purchases of Agency securities averaged $4.5 billion per month. Over the next five years, net
foreign purchases of Agency securities more than tripled to $14.9 billion per month (Treasury
International Capital, 2009). In its 1999 Annual Report, Fannie Mae predicted this shift, arguing
that its Agency debt will be “viewed by many investors as a liquid investment alternative to U.S.
Treasuries (page 89).” Roll (2004) argues that increases in GSE debt issuance were essential to
tap international capital markets and meet the growing demand for U.S. mortgage borrowing.
Unlike other issuers of asset-backed securities (ABS), Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac
retained the credit risk on their MBS in the event that the mortgages that collateralized the SPV
defaulted. As a result, increasing the share of mortgages financed through debt had no impact on
Fannie and Freddie’s exposure to credit risk. It did, however, increase the GSEs’ exposure to
interest rate risk because of the prepayment option embedded in mortgages. It was the interest
rate risk from funding negative convexity assets with debt that led Greenspan and others to argue
for limits on the size of the GSEs’ balance sheets. Jaffee (2003) argues that the GSEs interest
rate risk management systems were not robust to large movements in interest rates and also
failed to account for basis risk. Passmore (2005) estimates that market participants would
require the GSEs to hold much smaller portfolios and much more equity to deal with interest rate
Page 6
risk if their debt were not implicitly guaranteed. Hubbard (2003) finds Fannie Mae’s interest rate
risk management practices able to effectively manage interest rate risk over most conceivable
scenarios. Miller and Pearce (2003) and Miller (2006) find that the GSEs are less exposed to
large moves in interest rates than the thrift industry. Finally, Stiglitz, Orszag, and Orszag (2002)
find that the probability of an unfavorable interest rate move of the magnitude necessary to cause
a Fannie Mae default is substantially less than one in 500,000.
Interest rate risk is measured through a “duration gap” that provides a measure of the
effective duration of assets minus the effective duration of liabilities, adjusted for leverage.
When the duration gap is zero, interest rate risk is effectively “immunized” for any reasonable
change in interest rates. As seen in Chart 1, Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac had much different
tolerance for interest rate risk in the earlier part of the decade. In August of 2002, Fannie Mae’s
duration gap was –14 months, which suggests that its mortgage portfolio was prepaying at
speeds the risk managers did not anticipate, leaving the firm badly exposed to further declines in
interest rates. Interestingly, this dramatic deviation in risk did not show up in debt spreads, as
Page 7
the yield on Freddie Mac’s debt was actually 15 to 20 basis points wider than Fannie’s despite its
much safer risk profile.
In summary, the debate regarding GSE policy concerned the growth in the GSEs’
retained portfolios and the interest rate risk associated with leveraged investments in negative
convexity assets. Critics argued that the portfolios created systemic risks without providing
lower mortgage rates. Defenders of the GSEs argued that Agency debt was more attractive to
investors than MBS and that the interest rate risks were far overstated. The data from 2002-2003
suggest that Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac had much different interest rate risk management
systems in place but market participants did not penalize Fannie Mae for its relatively lax
standards. Interestingly, both sides in the debate seemed to agree that the credit risk posed by
mortgages holdings was trivial or otherwise undeserving of serious scrutiny. The reforms
recommended by the Federal Reserve would have allowed the GSEs to continue to aggregate
unlimited amounts of mortgage credit risk so long as these mortgage purchases were financed
through the issuance of MBS.
3. The Evolution of the U.S. Mortgage Market
As the policy debate raged on, the structure of the U.S. mortgage market was changing
dramatically. In 2003, Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac accounted for 52.3% of all residential
mortgage loans (Federal Reserve and Monthly Funding Summaries). Within three years, their
share of total outstanding mortgage debt (retained portfolio plus net MBS outstanding) had fallen
by 8 percentage points to 44%. During this same period, their retained portfolios declined to
13.6% of the total mortgage market from 23% in 2003.
This shift involve two related, but distinct, developments: (1) the share of total outstanding
mortgage debt financed by the issuance of non-Agency asset-backed securities (ABS) nearly
doubled over the course of only three years; and (2) the origination of non-traditional mortgage
products, like subprime and Alt-A loans, grew exponentially during this period. As seen in Chart
2, from 2003 to 2006, the net amount of mortgage debt held by asset-backed security issuers
(ABS Issuers) and “Finance Companies” increased dramatically. ABS Issuers are off-balance
sheet vehicles sponsored by banks and other financial intermediaries that finance mortgage
purchases by issuing notes to investors. Finance companies perform a similar function, but
generally issue notes that are the obligation of the company itself instead of being tied to the
underlying collateral. Finance companies can be a mortgage financier like GMAC, or an asset-
backed security conduit. The stock of mortgages used to collateralize non-Agency ABS (the
combination of the two subcategories) grew by more than 25% per year and exceeded 40%
growth in 2005 and 2006. From 2002-2006, the dollar value of outstanding mortgages financed
through non-Agency securitization increased by 239%, from $774 billion to $2.63 trillion. The
non-agency ABS market share roughly doubled during this period, from 13% of all residential
mortgages in 2002 to 26.7% of total household mortgage debt outstanding in 2006 (Fed Z-1,
Table 2 illustrates the growth in the non-traditional mortgage market. “Subprime” loans
are made to borrowers that have low credit ratings and other undesirable characteristics that
would make them unable to qualify for a traditional, prime mortgage. This segment of the
Page 11
Agency securitization market contracted.4 As shown in Chart 2, 2007 was also the year that
Fannie and Freddie’s combined book of business grew by over 10%, adding over $600 billion in
net new mortgage debt.
Not every mortgage loan purchased by ABS issuers was subprime or Alt-A; likewise, not
every subprime or Alt-A loan found its way into a non-Agency ABS pool. Yet, it is seems clear
that subprime and Alt-A mortgage markets would not have grown so dramatically without
securitization, and the non-Agency ABS markets would not have grown without mortgage loans
to serve as the underlying collateral for those securities. While it is not clear how much of the
net increase in mortgage debt came from subprime and Alt-A loans, it is clear that non-Agency
securitization financed 75% of the gross origination of these products (GAO, 2009).
It is important to recognize that this shift in the mortgage finance market also occurred in
the context of rapidly increasing housing prices in much of the country, but especially in
California, Arizona, Florida, and Nevada. As shown in Chart 4, by early 2005 the year-over-year
price increases in the ten and twenty city Case-Shiller composite index had been running at over
10% per year for three years. The dramatic price growth led some to argue that the move to non-
traditional products was driven by affordability issues (Kling, 2009), as much of the purchase
volume of subprime and Alt-A loans was likely homebuyers who could not have otherwise
purchased the home. This is consistent with previous Fed research (Feldman, 2001) which found
that Fannie and Freddie made a limited contribution to homeownership rates precisely because
4 It is important to note that the subprime and Alt-A loan originations in Chart 2 are volume or “flow” statistics that
capture the amount of new loans originated in a given year (GAO, 2009), while the non-Agency Securitization
measures the net change in the dollar value of mortgage debt held by these securitization vehicles. Therefore there
is not a one-to-one correspondence. Since, as shown in Table 3, over half of subprime loans and over one-third of
Alt-A loans were used to refinance existing debt, the volume statistics incorporate loans used to retire existing debt
in addition to net new mortgage obligations. Separating the net new debt from refinancing on these loans is
difficult, especially because over half of the subprime loans during this period were for “cash-out” refinancing. A
portion of these loans add incrementally to the aggregate amount of mortgage debt outstanding while most of the
proceeds go to retire existing debt.
Page 12
the marginal buyer could not afford the large down payments Fannie and Freddie generally
required.
However, it is just as likely as causality ran in the opposite direction. As is clear from
Table 2, only one-third of subprime originations and one-half of Alt-A loans were used to
purchase homes. The majority of subprime mortgages were actually cash-out refinancings,
Page 13
20% down payment only allows a borrower to leverage his savings five times; a 3% down
payment allows the same borrower to leverage his down payment 33-times. As confidence in
continued price increases and competition from new products reduced average down payments,
prices may have risen in response to the increased leverage in the system.
Whatever the functional form of the relationship between non-Agency ABS, subprime
mortgages, and housing prices, the alternative mortgage market came to a crashing halt in 2007,
after the year/year change in house prices turned negative. As seen in Chart 5 (Fed Z-1, 2007),
the annual net increase in mortgage debt had actually been lagging the net increase in the value
of household residential real estate from 2000 to 2005. This allowed more debt to be incurred
without disruption. That changed in 2006, when mortgaged debt increased by nearly $1 trillion,
on net, while the value of residential real estate grew by about $500 billion. In 2007, the
mortgage market added $600 billion in incremental debt but the value of the underlying
residential real estate collateral (including newly constructed homes) fell by $1.4 trillion, causing
the entire system to collapse.
Page 14
4. The GSEs Role in the Alternative Mortgage Market
The data in the previous section are entirely inconsistent with the hypothesis that Fannie Mae
and Freddie Mac were responsible for the ensuring crisis. Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac could
only purchase “conforming” mortgages judged to be of “investment” quality. Neither of these
terms is defined in law, aside from a formal cap on the size of the mortgages eligible for
purchase (Kling, 2009). According to annual reports, this generally meant that mortgage
borrowers had to have FICO scores of over 620, a down payment of more than 10%, and be fully
documented. Table 3 lists the percentage of loans low FICO or high LTV mortgages purchased
mortgages because these securities were “goals rich” (Lockhart, 2009). Fannie and Freddie were
required to meet affordable housing goals, set annually by the Department of Housing and Urban
Development (HUD) in accordance with The Federal Housing Enterprises Financial Safety and
Soundness Act of 1992. The purchase of non-Agency ABS backed by subprime mortgages
counted towards meeting these goals because the underlying mortgages were made to borrowers
Page 15
who otherwise could not have gained access to mortgage credit. Indeed, Fannie Mae suggested
in its 2006 Annual Report that “because subprime mortgages tended to meet many of the HUD
goals and subgoals,” the decline in subprime origination that year “has further limited our ability
to meet these goals” (page 21).
A typical non-Agency ABS involves a “waterfall” payment structure. Instead of a traditional
“pass-through,” the ABS note holders are paid according to their seniority, with senior tranches
getting paid first and suffering losses from defaults on the underlying collateral, if any, last. The size
of the tranches is chosen to achieve AAA ratings on the senior portion, with the amount of
subordinated securities adjusted as necessary to provide the overcollateralization required by rating
agencies (Hu, 2007). Fannie and Freddie were major buyers of the AAA piece of the ABS. The
remaining, junior pieces were then generally sold into collateralized debt obligation (CDO) pools.
According to Freddie Mac’s 2006 Annual Report, “more than 99.9 percent” of its non-Agency ABS
were rated AAA. Until 2007, Fannie Mae also bought exclusively AAA non-Agency ABS and
added only “limited amounts” of other investment grade, non-Agency ABS (Fannie Mae, 2007).
Neither GSE had any exposure to CDOs (Fannie Mae, 2007, p. 97; Lockhart, 2008).
Estimating the amount of subprime and Alt-A ABS purchased by the GSEs during this
period is difficult because of differing levels of disclosures provided. Freddie Mac provides the
dollar amount of “Other Mortgage Securities” purchased for each year, which include all non-
Agency ABS, including Prime Jumbo and other types of non-subprime ABS. From 2001-2007,
Freddie Mac acquired $527 billion of these securities, with the largest purchase volume coming in